Academia.eduAcademia.edu
Beyond jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal Fortier, Jana ProQuest Dissertations and Theses; 1995; ProQuest Dissertations & Theses Full Text pg. n/a Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
i BEYOND JAJMANI: THE COMPLEXITY OF INDIGENOUS LABOR RELATIONS IN WESTERN NEPAL Jana Fortier Under the Supervision of Assistant Professor Katherine Ann Bowie at the University of Wisconsin-Madison This dissertation examines the logic of exchange and power in Nepali society through an examination of labor exchange. Researchers have examined the jajmãni system, known throughout South Asia as a ritualized system of reciprocal rights and duties among castes. Yet many other labor exchange practices exist in Jãjarkoë District, western Nepal. Therefore, this dissertation asks, “Is jajmãni a self-contained system of productive social relations?” I conclude that jajmãni is one small part in a larger system of productive social relations. This dissertation explicates rules of practice for the range of management strategies used in Nepali farming and livestock herding. This dissertation focuses on work strategies known as khalo, jajmãni, hali, ãdhiyå, baure, parimã, and sahayog. These translate as "artisanship," "Brãhman priestly services," "plowing services," "sharecropping," "daily labor," "reciprocal exchange," and "labor gifting." Together, these practices constitute a system of ethnomanagement essential for small-scale production in Nepal. The method of ethnography used involved both qualitative and quantitative data collection. Conversational interviews were used to understand the cultural construction of labor relations. Socio-economic surveys were administered in Jãjarkoë District and two hundred and sixty households were analyzed using Pearson Product Moment ii correlations. The data support the hypothesis that combinations of named labor practices enhance elites’ social control over non-elites. Thus, using all of the labor practices, and not simply jajmãni, elites engage in negotiated labor exchanges which are often structurally unequal. Structurally unequal exchange is part of an economic system labeled “paternalism.” Paternalism is marked by unequal exchange; patron-clientism (e.g., jajmãni); land ownership as a primary marker of social status; prominent barter and labor exchange systems; and workers continuing to control their own means of production. In summary, Nepalese indigenous labor relations solidify Nepali social caste and class hierarchies; employ paternalism as a mechanism of unequal exchange; continue as viable strategies despite intrusions of capitalism; and form a network of labor strategies rather than one monolithic jajmãni system. Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 1 1 INTRODUCTION TO THE COMPLEXITY OF INDIGENOUS LABOR The hilly terrain of western Nepal is best suited for labor intensive farming systems rather than capital intensive farming. Understandably, Nepali small scale producers have developed many types of labor management. For example, small scale producers can negotiate their grain and livestock with artisans and priests through the labor practices known as khalo and jajmãni. Households can exchange labor (parimã) or gift their labor to others (sahayog). Larger landowners can obtain sharecropping tenants (adhiyå, kut), bonded laborers (haliyã), or daily laborers (baure, jãladãri). In South Asia researchers have explored the ritual and economic aspects of jajmãni and haliyã as systems of patronage and bonded labor. Yet jajmãni and haliyã are only two practices out of many, and they are part of a greater gestalt of labor relations. My goal in writing this dissertation is to uncover the greater totality of labor relations in Jãjarkot District, Nepal. In studying the labor relations in this area, I envision a better understanding of the logic of exchange and power in Nepali agrarian society. Applied anthropologists, theoretically oriented anthropologists, and cultural researchers are beginning to appreciate the logic of various economic relationships such as pastoralism, feudalism, domestic based production, etc. which previously have been subsumed under the study of economics from a capitalist perspective. Sometimes these economic systems outside the realm of capitalism are termed "non-capitalist modes of production," "pre-capitalist economic formations," "non-western economic systems," or "indigenous economics." Usually the epithets, in a Eurocentric fashion, refer back to capitalism as defined by the Western historical experience. This dissertation is about the economic and social rules of appropriate behavior which clearly lie outside the caricature of Western capitalism. Through the experiences of various tenants, landlords, labor donors, and labor receivers resident in western Nepal, I present a representational structure of labor relations which are dominated by patronage, asymmetry, and small scale production. I intuit that cultural researchers outside of South Asia may find in these labor relationships some similarities with work in other places. Universal are the experiences of sharecropping, casual labor, bonded labor, and labor reciprocity, yet particular are the lived experiences of work. 2 In this dissertation I make four main assertions about the social organization of indigenous labor in Nepal. First, indigenous labor practices are efficient, necessary, and valuable contributions to current Nepalese agriculture, far from "uneconomical" as previously asserted (S. Epstein 1967). I will show that indigenous labor practices enable households to carry out small scale production in a region of steep inclines, regular landslips, little or no irrigation, fatigued soils, and muddy monsoon trails. Second, contrary to "degradationist" theories postulating the decline of jajmãni and other indigenous labor practices elsewhere in South Asia, (e.g., Elder 1970), indigenous labor continues to be the organizing force behind effective agricultural, livestock, and craft production throughout rural regions of Nepal. Third, while capitalist wage labor is present in Jãjarkot District, households continue to rely primarily on barter, labor exchange, patronage, and other non-capitalist strategies.1 By subsuming all work within a capitalist wage labor framework, I argue that we cannot clearly understand a non-capitalist logic of production. In short, Jãjarkot households manipulate "multiple production forms" (MPF), a term I use to describe the interactions between systems such as patronage and capitalism. Fourth, labor practices are often exploitative of one partner. Contrary to many depictions of indigenous labor as "forms of cooperation" (Worsley 1971; Messerschmidt 1981), households in this caste society often reciprocate and appropriate labor based on close scrutiny of the composite value of each labor partner. Thus I argue that "unequal exchange" is the norm in social relationships rather than a careful balancing of labor inputs. In short, implicit within seemingly cooperative labor exchange lie many roots of exploitation. Following from the this last point, I argue that local labor exchanges help define the social status of Jãjarkoti households. I will show that one's status and practice as landlord:tenant, creditor:debtor, patron:artisan, labor donor:receiver, and employer:laborer constitute fundamental power relations which inform one's position in society. This dissertation is further grounded upon two theoretical perspectives. First, I uphold the ubiquitous presence of women as laborers, patrons, artisans, and other productive workers. In almost all past literature on South Asian labor, men have served as the sole example. We have no clue as to what female tailors, pipe makers, fieldworkers, carpenters, etc. are doing and how their work is related to their positions in society. In my dissertation I explore the roles of women in the management of indigenous labor although the focus is not solely on women's production. Second, work and labor have strong symbolic Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 3 significance. One can not fully understand the social organization of indigenous labor until he or she apprehends the cultural construction of labor action (Comaroff and Comaroff 1987). Thus I explicate the ideological as well as the material. I maintain that verbal discourse and non-verbal symbols are actions which can influence others. The social status of households is a result of their material and ideological actions. Verbal and non-verbal action, as well as socioeconomic conditions, both contribute to the social organization of indigenous labor. In the following sections I outline some of the underlying environmental and economic conditions which create the background for understanding indigenous labor relations in Nepal. The purpose of this introductory chapter is to familiarize the reader with the research site, Nepalese indigenous labor practices, and some of the issues surrounding labor and exchange. I chose to conduct research in Jãjarkot District, west Nepal because, on the surface, it appears rather homogeneous, socially stable, with few historically iconographic events. Jãjarkot District has neither experienced the history of environmental degradation characteristic of central highland Nepal nor the population explosion and forest clearings of the Gangetic plains (terãi), in southern Nepal. No large development projects have altered social relations in Jãjarkot such as in the east of Nepal. There are only rural villages which are partly but not unduly dependent on large cities such as Nepalganj, Kathmandu, or Bharatnagar. I chose the western middle hills region because of its overtly slow social change hoping that 'indigenous forms of cooperation' had not degraded into wage labor. The people of Jãjarkot are part of Hindu agrarian society and like the vast majority of Nepalese, Jãjarkot's residents are also farmers. There exists a stereotype, even in the minds of urban Nepalese, that rural farmers are ignorant, their ways are backward, they need bikãs, or developing. As S. Pigg noted, elite educated and urbanized Nepalese are so culturally distant from rural Nepal that for them to visit in a village is tantamount to visiting an alien country. Pigg highlighted the theme of rural people as ignorant: "The social construction of the villager is built on this theme of ignorance. People who work in development, from low-level functionaries to policy makers, are acutely aware of the chasm 4 between the attitudes and habits they promote and the ones that exist. As individuals they are positioned precisely at the points of blockage, the point beyond which what they know about real villages and real villagers cannot be translated upward to the language of generalities spoken in the world of development. These people tell each other and foreign visitors that the villagers are the problem, identifying them as "people who don't understand' (kurã bujhdeinan). (1992:506-507). My dissertation deconstructs the stereotypes of poor, rural, ignorant farmers commonly held in urban media and international politics. Rural farmers are not ignorant; they know about patronage, sharecropping, labor reciprocity, group labor, bonded labor, and how to give gifts of labor. They know how to efficiently mete out their resources, though it is not usually through a system of wage labor. Though it is not commonly recognized, one form of indigenous knowledge is that of managing people and resources efficiently and effectively. Western styles of wage labor, capitalism, and class relations represent one style of labor management, one uncommon in Jãjarkot. From a development perspective then, decades of failure to improve Nepalese standards of living is directly related to development decision-makers' ignorance of Nepalese productive relations.2 Though my dissertation primarily elucidates the social organization of indigenous labor, from an applied perspective my research represents a means of understanding indigenous knowledge of labor management for more effective development policy. Indigenous labor practices in Jãjarkot District consist primarily of sharecropping (adhiyå, kut), labor reciprocity (parimã, kãm gardna joun), gifts of labor (sahayog), bonded labor (hali), casual labor (baure, jãla), and patronage (khalo, jajmãni). Other practices, such as wage labor, litigating disputes, guarding livestock, forests, or harvests, lending/borrowing land, grain and cash, donating labor to the state, are peripheral to my thesis subject but are nevertheless important aspects of the overall social organization of indigenous labor in Jãjarkot. Relations of production focused on capitalist wage labor3 are related to indigenous labor practices though they are not the focus of this dissertation. Basics in the Social Organization of Indigenous Knowledge Lack of Understanding of Indigenous Knowledge Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 5 Don Messerschmidt’s article, “Indigenous forms of cooperation: Implications for development” (1981) has been one of the few articles about Nepalese labor to explore the value of local labor practices (see also Ishii 1982). He asserted that traditional forms of cooperation are a valuable resource in farming communities. He contributed greatly to a movement in Nepal today which explores the role of local forestry management practices (Metz 1989a), irrigation cooperatives (Yoder 1986), and credit cooperatives (Messerschmidt 1972; L. Caplan 1972). He argued that community developers should pay special attention to indigenous forms of cooperation and consider using these in development implementation. Messerschmidt has not, however, addressed the role of indigenous ‘forms of cooperation’ within the overall social organization of Nepalese society. He has also failed to examine the exploitative aspects of labor exchange and group labor parties. Cooperation as a concept is meaningless without its counterpart, exploitation. Many of the indigenous labor practices which Messerschmidt or other developers consider implementing in development projects are poorly understood. Practices which appear egalitarian often have less observable exploitative characteristics. Two forms of cooperation, reciprocal labor and gifts of labor (or delayed general reciprocity) are arguably egalitarian. Often labor relationships exist between families of equal social status with roughly equal amounts of land. In these cases, reciprocity is equitable and egalitarian. Yet even egalitarian labor exchanges can transform into unequal exchanges when one partner is a high caste and the other is low caste, or other inequalities are present. If a household uses gifts of labor to patronize another household, the exchange is less a gift of labor with the expectation of later return than political fealty in the guise of egalitarianism. In the following chapters I discuss the way in which labor practices place households in positions of both cooperation and exploitation among their neighbors. A Feminist Understanding of Indigenous Labor If development functionaries and anthropologists know little about the social organization of indigenous knowledge, they know even less about women’s roles in creating, doing, and transforming indigenous knowledge. In other parts of the world, anthropologists have explored women's productive roles: celebrated examples include A. Weiner’s Women of Value, Men of Renown and Inalienable Possessions; M. Strathern’s The Gender of the gift ; P. Caplan’s article “Gender, culture, and modes of 6 production”; or one of my favorites, Bananas, Beaches, and Bases: The Role of Women in International Politics by C. Enloe. Most literature concerning ‘women's work’ however revolves around domestic labor, marriage arrangements, gardens, and midwives. Ursula Sharma’s Women, Work, and Property, while on the whole excellent in detail and ethnography, focuses narrowly on women’s economic positions through purdah and a male kinship perspective. In Nepal, Lynn Bennett’s Dangerous Wives and Sacred Sisters is outstanding research, but again it defines women through their kinship roles to males. The work continues to unquestioningly accept patriarchal Hindu premises about ideal kinship relations. The main limitations of the female perspective defined solely through a woman's sexual-cultural construction as mother, wife, or sister to men are briefly that first, the breadth of difference among women in the vast number of cultures is falsely universalized to a western orthodoxy of woman as mother, wife, etc. As gender research has pointed out (Caplan 1988; Etienne 1979; Goodale 1980; Shostak 1981) the cultural construction of such categories as wife, mother, and sister vary enormously across cultures. Second, women’s' roles as anything outside male linked kinship categories remain stunted analytically until women's productive roles dissociate from androcentric perspectives. Roles as "Wife" and "Mother" are important but they cannot describe the whole productive world of Jajarkoti women. Though not all ethnographies situate women as kinship links between men, Henrietta Moore points out: Kinship relations, particularly where they are examined in terms of their role in political and jural structures, can turn out to be the study of kinbased links between men, and women are considered merely one of the mechanisms for establishing those links. (1988:132) This dissertation does not marginalize women’s work by confining analysis to Western orthodoxy of what constitutes women's work, such as mothering, housekeeping, or gardening. I avoid the largely western bias of seeing women through a lens of the domestic versus the public, such as viewing women primarily as housewives and men as artisans. Nepalese women in Jãjarkot do not conform to such a model. They actively carry out major farm work, organize labor gangs, make decisions about production and payments, and conduct a host of other tasks which would Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 7 be poorly understood through the domestic - public dichotomy. Rather than discuss social relationships as kinship roles of "sister," "mother," "daughter," etc. within a patriline, I focus on households, not individuals, and the productive relations of households as parts of castes and classes. In this dissertation I identify women less as “sisters” (of brothers), “mothers” (of sons), "daughters-in law" (in husband's household) or “wives” (of husbands) and more as tenant, landowner, pipemaker, tailor, labor organizer, patient, forest guard, family planning educator, etc. The paternal Hindu stereotype of a patrilocal repressive extended family is often misleading and wrong for Jãjarkot families. Love marriages, matrilocality, female remarriage, female heads of households, and brideservice by the grooms are not uncommon. For example, many women in Nepal are effectively heads of households. Their husbands have either died or left them due to remarriage or migrancy. Many young women stay with their natal family if the family is wealthy and their husbands join the wife's family. Also important, the practice of jãri is common in Jãjarkot. In jãri a woman leaves her husband for another and the second husband reimburses the first for his loss and grief.4 From my interviews jãri appears as a safety mechanism for women to escape from unproductive or unhealthy marriages or simply a means for them to become upwardly mobile. Though the Hindu 'Great Traditions' of patriarchal kinship and marriage are known accepted ideals, in reality the 'little traditions' of local practice often predominate. Finally, I focus frequently on women in the social organization of indigenous labor to counter previous androcentric research. Women's roles are nearly absent from research on South Asian patronage systems, often glossed as the jajmãni system. As we come to understand local labor relations, it becomes apparent that women do much of the secondary and preparatory work of artisanship. In this dissertation we shall encounter women who sew with their husbands, but who do not use the sewing machine; women who prepare the soil for pottery making, but who do not shape the pots; women who collect and negotiate payments from agriculturalists, but who do not perform the artisanship themselves. In many ways these women micro-manage artisanship, but they seldom perform the primary artisanal tasks. While I study households, and not women's work specifically, half the people with whom I spoke are women. This dissertation views labor relations partly through the perspectives of these women using anecdotes, translations, and references about female laborers and owners. 8 Applying Indigenous Knowledge In general, not only does an androcentric view inform social studies but a Western biased perspective pervades our understanding of Nepalese social relations. Nepalese development and banking planners, for example, have only used wage labor and institutional lending to stimulate development. A better question might be, 'why do low castes so often turn to indigenous lending practices'?5 or, 'why do farmers use adhiyå (sharecropping), baure (casual called labor), khalo (patronage), etc. rather than wage labor?' If planners understand why indigenous practices remain viable, they might incorporate them into development plans. Jãjarkot people might evince self esteem for their practical labor methods rather than shame that they are so “backward”. I examined how Nepalese NGO’s and foreign development agencies omitted local labor. Development projects, like the Karnali-Bheri Integrated Rural Development Project (which was projected to come to Jãjarkot but ran out of funds during implementation in neighboring Districts), never considered incorporating indigenous labor relations. Developers ignored farmers’ social conditions, neglecting to address the role of reciprocal labor, patronage, or even indigenous lending practices. Seldom do local development projects seriously evaluate their impact on sharecroppers. Seldom do development reports admit that their project loans are meant for medium and large landowners. The failure of HMG compulsory savings plans in the A.D. 1960’s, called Sãjhã, revealed little forethought regarding the practical realities of indigenous Nepalese loan and savings practices (HMG/N 1962). While the evaluation of how indigenous labor practices are incorporated into development planning remains an important consideration, this dissertation restricts its comments on the interface between indigenous practices and development to the occasional reference. Patronage in Historical Material Perspective One practice that researchers 6 studied extensively, jajmãni patronage common in northern India, got the reputation for being (an exotic, nonwestern) "system of smoothly related social roles based on caste" (e.g. Bailey 1957). Yet the totality of 'smoothly related social roles' is actually, I argue, based on not only jajmãni, but sharecropping, bonded labor, local lending, reciprocal labor, and labor gifting in a matrix of social rules and appropriate behavior specific to the region. It is a mistake, I argue, to ignore other aspects of the management of labor besides jajmãni because Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 9 we simply reify the practice of jajmãni while at the same time misunderstand real relations of production. Early western ethnographers failed to recognize the complexity of interdependence between forms of labor relations (Wiser 1936; Bailey 1957; Gould 1958). Though interested in the jajmãni "system " of South Asian productive relations but they failed entirely to understand how jajmãni integrated with other labor practices. For example, Lewis and Barnouw credit the first study of jajmãni relations by William Wiser (actually Charlotte Wiser 1930) published the first detailed study): It is greatly to Wiser’s credit that he was able to characterize jajmãni relations as a system (emph. original). Some knowledge of this system is crucial for an understanding of the economic aspects of caste in rural India (1967:110).7 Lewis and Barnouw failed to see that, in addition to jajmãni relations, sharecropping, reciprocity, group labor, and loans are crucial economic aspects of caste relations. Jajmãni is not so much a system in itself as a part of a greater system. Many early writers created artificial boundaries of analysis of patronage which neglected to link other parts of the social formation. Rather than essentialized 'bounded systems' anthropologists have begun exploring the greater totality of which jajmãni is one part (C. Fuller 1989; Breman 1974; Brass 1986, Raheja 1988b in symbolic perspective), yet a truly holistic understanding of the interaction of labor forms remains unwritten. My work begins to address this lacuna. My dissertation emphasizes the integrated quality of labor relations. To create a more holistic rendering of the social organization of indigenous labor one must look at regional material history. In Jãjarkot material considerations for understanding indigenous labor relations include land ownership patterns, tax collection changes, new land surveys, political power shifts, caste hierarchies, and divisions of labor. Amount of land ownership connotes status as "owner" or "laborer," for example. District Center high caste elites own the largest land holdings, about two hectare per household. District Center low castes own on average less than one half of a hectare per household. The small land holding of low castes are part of the reason they enter artisanship and unskilled labor much more frequently than high castes. In order to understand patterns of land ownership, I explore Jãjarkot’s tenurial history dating from the mid-nineteenth century A.D. 10 Tribute to a political elite was common in the early part of the century, despite national tax regulations. Jãjarkot, one of three remaining feudal kingdoms, relied on patronage and tribute to supply royal elites. Today however, elites command no tribute. The tax office collects taxes on individually owned parcels and the King of Jãjarkot lives in Kathmandu. The remaining extended royal family who live in Jãjarkot own large amounts of land, usually as absentee landlords, and hire sharecroppers to work the land. British indirect rule, so central to an understanding of Indian tenurial history, plays a smaller, more elusive part in Nepal’s and Jãjarkot District’s historical land tenure relations. Jãjarkot kings sided with the British during the 1857 A.D. Lucknow uprisings, sending Jãjarkoti troops to India. British emissaries, however, never visited Jãjarkot District according to written records. British legal changes in India had an impact on land and labor legal decisions in Nepal through imitation of some changes in Indian laws. Slavery, for example, was outlawed by A.D. 1930 in Nepal after it was outlawed in India. Jãjarkot elites were influenced by British indirect rule ongoing in India, but they were not constrained by British directives. Nepalese tax revenue collection never imitated British fashion in India, such as using the British streamlined version of India’s Zamindar tax collection system in northern India (Frykenberg 1977). Nor was Jãjarkot District targeted for any nationalist development endeavors, such as railroad building or construction of motorable roads. Even into this century Jãjarkot royalty conscripted compulsory labor and their royal relatives’ elephants in neighboring Districts for construction of early development projects. With little British influence in Jãjarkot, indigenous labor remained a prominent feature of social relations rather than dissolving into relations based on disengaged ties of wage labor. Throughout the chapters, whether they be concerned with theory, a review of the literature, or an elucidation of indigenous labor relations in Jãjarkot, I try to enlighten the reader about the function and structure of particular labor practices in their local context. I describe local versions of sharecropping, bonded labor, casual labor, reciprocal labor, gifts of labor, and economic exchanges of khalo and jajmãni within their social matrices. I use a feminist perspective and show women as managers, workers, farmers, and actors who cooperate with and exploit other neighbors using indigenous labor practices. I develop a qualitative and quantitative blend of information for understanding indigenous labor relations. I remind the reader that well documented practices such as Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 11 jajmãni are only parts of a greater totality of material social relations. Doing this, I focus on the interface between land ownership and patronage; bonded labor and caste status; laborer status and artisanal status in the society. Indigenous Labor Relations Patronage and Sharecropping More than simply 'forms of cooperation', the successful management of indigenous labor practices involves smooth interaction of a household with their neighbors, including proper leverage of social statuses and resources. Successful households incorporate several styles of labor management, such as sharecropping, casual labor, and labor reciprocity. Below I briefly define and describe the major forms of labor which form the subject of this dissertation. I think of these labor practices as the tools for managing agrarian production in Jãjarkot. In Jãjarkot jajmãni is a practice in which a Brãhman priest conducts services on a long term basis for a patron family in exchange for a portion of the patron's resources. In Jãjarkot the notion of jajmãni extends no farther, especially not to artisans in general, as it does in India. The Bãhun priest's patron is known as the jajamãn (Skt: yajamãna). The priest is known as Bãhun or Bãmni if a woman8. The idea of jajmãni is linked to religious contexts, as one man described it: "jajmãni is a religious activity." In Jãjarkot the term khalo is used to refer to an artisan who conducts services on a long term basis for a patron family in exchange for a portion of the patron's grain harvest. The patron is known as the bista, khalo dine mãnchhe, or sauji. The artisan is known by his or her occupation, such as Damãi (tailor), Kãmi (ironsmith), or Gãine (singer). The relationship is often of several generations duration. The relationship can loosely be described as one of patronage in many, but not all, cases. In wage and market driven societies, money or reified objects (cash, shell, betel, cowry, leaf bundles) serve as a primary exchange. Jajmãni, fundamentally a barter system, often intertwines with cash arrangements. Jajmãni, famous throughout India, is locally called “khalo“ in dealing with artisans and “jajmãni” when one deals with Bãhun priests. The following display variations of khalo and jajmãni as they might occur in two households in Jãjarkot: a) When Tika Bãdini (entertainer/prostitute caste) trimmed the clay pipe, chilim, along the 12 spinning chord, she murmured, "This makes 200 chilim, ready to fire. Maybe our khal, grain payment/portion, will feed us through the next month." Tika's daughter-in-law sat on the ground nearby and inscribed patterns into the pipes. "People like the diamond, clover, spade, and heart shapes that I put on the chilim. Most of the pipes we give for a mãnã, handful, of grain. Some people are khalo dine mãnchhes, patrons, from long ago but most just come now and then. If there is a fair, melã, we'll make chilim to sell in the melã. b) All artisans, and most priests, have long standing ties to patrons. Gita, a Bãhun priest's daughter, said, "We get all our things from our jajamãn, patron. This is the Bãhun's sidã, portion, like the khal of other castes. We get as payment cow, plate, incense burner, bed frame, blanket, new water jug, spade, knife, rope, cooking pot." Researchers tend to study only jajmãni but they rarely investigate both unskilled labor and jajmãni together as parts of one ‘system’. As Breman who worked in Gujarat complained, The usual definition of this system [jajmãni] as a mechanism of exchange of goods and services among the various castes on the local level would, at first sight, comprise the relation between landlords and agricultural laborers as well. Yet many authors do not regard the latter [agricultural laborers] as partners in the jajmãni system, because, for one thing, the differentiation within the agrarian castes was not sufficiently recognized.” (1974:13)9 I agree with Breman in that we need to envision jajmãni ties of patronage as related to other extant labor practices in Jãjarkot. Understanding jajmãni means understanding the place of jajmãni among other material relationships, such as sharecropping. Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 13 Jae Khatri, (Chhetri caste), is proud to say he sharecrops five parcels of land for landlords living in the District Center. "Doing adhiyå, sharecropping, ensures my family's food needs. I sharecrop for four different landowners and produce just enough wheat after splitting the harvest in half with the landowner to last until the corn crop is ready for harvest." But he complained that there weren't any neighbors this year willing to exchange labor (parimã). Instead, Jae had to pay Rs. 700 for female rice transplanters, ropãrni. "Truly", he says, "I would rather do the parimã than pay so much money." Adhiyå (sharecropping) is an agreement between a land owner and tenant. The historically agreed upon division of the produce is one-half the surplus divided between the parties. Although there exist descriptions of tenancy agreements, the significance of Adhiyå tenancy in terms of the social and economic relations of landowner and tenant has not been studied. Regmi, 1976, 1978; Hodgson, 1874; Pandey, 1970; Tucci, 1956, outlined the de jure form of Adhiyå but in practice there exists a complex set of obligations between tenant and landlord which extend beyond the stated agreement of division of surplus. Simple Labor Reciprocity, Casual Labor, Gifts of Labor Farmers perform parimã, simple labor reciprocity, at intensive work periods throughout the year. In Jãjarkot, two or more households help each other during rice transplanting, millet weeding, and harvests. The households meet and agree to rotate families' work in an organized fashion, including shifting irrigation channels to flood rice lands. Jae Khatri preferred to use reciprocal exchange. Simple reciprocity is practical because it builds up neighborly relations, avoiding the isolation and expense of paying workers a wage. A frequently used practice in Jãjarkot, baure or casual labor, is more common than full wage labor. To do baure, farmers call labor (? >Nep:bolãunu) literally from “anyone walking on the road.” They pay the workers at the end of the day and feed them during the day generously with three full meals. Baure has an advantage over reciprocal labor according to rural farmers because one need not waste time organizing the 14 rotation of farms and laborers. Laborers can get a lot of work done in just one or two days whereas reciprocal laborers move slowly from one land parcel to the next. An important labor practice, yet difficult to gauge exactly how people value it, is sahayog, meaning literally “help.” As labor help, sahayog implies no obligation to return the gift of labor. In reality neighbors who give help generally receive labor help at some undefined time in the future. Thus sahayog constitutes a form of generalized delayed labor reciprocity between two persons and sometimes two households. Gifts of labor are important in farming communities because it is often hard to find help under poor circumstances, such as if a person falls ill or the men folk migrate to India for the winter. When a farmer looks for labor help, sometimes she recruits reciprocal labor, other times she may go around the village recruiting or ‘calling’ for laborers, and as a more informal method she might go to a neighbor‘s home and request help, sahayog. Thus sahayog, parimã, and baure labor forms flow reasonably and efficiently into one another, depending on the needs of the farmer. When a laborer is obligated to work for a landowner it is known as haliyã in Jãjarkot. Nepali hal means "plow" implying that the bonded laborer's most salient duty is to plow for the lender/landowner. Although the constitution of the Kingdom of Nepal contains a provision against the practice of bonded labor, there are still people who become indebted to landowners. In the southern terãi the practice of unfree labor is known as kamaiyã. Kamaiyã appears to be a more severe form of servitude than haliyã (INSEC 1992). Jãjarkot landowners prefer hali rather than kamaiyã perhaps because Jãjarkot landowners have smaller land parcels than in the terãi. Jãjarkoti money-lenders/landowners only need bonded laborers for about five to ten days out of any month whereas terãi landowners produce cash crops (sugarcane, pineapple) and owns enough land to be able to support bonded laborers. In order to understand the social organization of indigenous labor we need to explore not only the practice of jajmãni but many more productive relations. We also need to understand the interplay of caste and class, the nature of cooperation and exploitation, and social rules of production, which are essentially about labor practice in Nepal’s overwhelming rural environment. Basics about Jãjarkot District Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 15 To present my main conclusions about land and income in Jãjarkot immediately, average land holding in one of my samples of rural villages (118 households over one days’ walk from the District Center) was 14.4 Ropãni [.73 ha.] for high castes and 5.1 Ropãni [.26 ha.] for low castes. 10 Average grain production was 18.4 muri (918 kg.) for high castes and 7.4 muri (368 Kg.) for low castes. Average income (cash and in-kind) is about $82/year from grain and livestock, $78/yr. from labor sales, $177/yr. from Business, $69/yr. from other sources, usually government work. This totals an average of $406/yr./household or $84/yr./capita. From this and my other socioeconomic surveys (SES) in the Jãjarkot Region I conclude that 1) Jãjarkot's rural areas are poverty stricken; 2) Jãjarkot is not fully within the market economy; 3) Jãjarkot households employ non-capitalist economic strictures to maintain a subsistence level of consumption and social reproduction; and 4) a combination of poverty, non-market and non-monetary economic strategies is operating. I now turn to the details underlying these economic circumstances. Jãjarkot District is located in the central middle hills region of western Nepal, surrounded by Rukum, Salyan, Dailekh, Surkhet, Kalikot, Jumlã, and Dolpã Districts. The Bheri River, which eventually joins the Karnali, flows from Dolpã District in the Himalayan mountains toward the terãi lowlands (northern Gangetic plain) and India. Smaller river systems throughout the District are important for fishing and irrigation. Jãjarkot has elevations of 600 to 5400 meters with permanent settlements reaching to 3300 meters and impermanent shelters (goths) on mountain ridges (lekhs) reaching to 3900 meters. The elevation at Khalaÿgã, the District Center and only Bazaar in Jãjarkot, is 1290 meters. There are no motorable roads in Jãjarkot; the main road from Rukum to the District Center is a wide avenue suitable for horses or foot travel and spans a distance of four hours' walk. Given the rocky steep outcroppings above the trail, workers must rebuild it every four or five years, after monsoon rains cause the road to deteriorate. Other roads are appropriate for horses to travel along, though few people own horses, or for foot walking. Main walking routes percolate out from the District Center toward Dailekh, Jumlã, Dolpã, and into the middle of Jãjarkot. The district can be traversed in about 3-4 days along these east, west, and central main routes. The total population of Jãjarkot district is estimated as of 1980 at 104,340 persons. The population ratio of male to female is 51.6% male to 48.4% female.11 Average household size is estimated at 5.5 persons. Population density in Jãjarkot district is 43.4 persons/km2. Since only 30.7% of total land area is cultivable, density/arable kilometer rises to 16 130.2 persons/km2. This is above the average for Nepal as a whole and slightly above the average for middle hill districts (His Majesty's Government/Nepal B. S. 2031; 1985). About 55% of the District Center region’s households are a Bãhun-Thãkuri-Chhetri high caste composition. About 25% of households are of Magar ethnicity, a hilly region ethnic group original to Nepal and located throughout Nepal’s middle hills. Another 10% or 15% of the population are low caste tailors (Damãi), ironsmiths (Kãmi), goldmiths (Sunãr), singers (Gãine), pipemaker/prostitute (Bãdi), coppersmith (Tamãrã/Tamãtã), and fisher/boating (Rawot) castes. The remaining 5% are outsiders in government jobs, ascetic castes (Jaisi, Jogi), and Newãr, Gurung and Thãru families migrated in from neighboring districts. Compared to terãi lowlands and Sherpa dominated highlands which are experiencing much immigration and emigration, Jãjarkot’s population make-up has not changed significantly in recent years. The opening up of farm land in the terãi has yet to motivate many households to permanently migrate south from Jãjarkot. Khalaÿgã Bazaar has approximately 200 houses with an estimated city population of 1,100 persons. The Bazaar has several Magar families, a half-Muslim family, and a community of Newãri shopkeepers. In addition, Khalaÿgã houses more than 30 government offices which employ persons from the whole of Nepal. This tends to give Khalaÿgã Bazaar a greater proportion of Bãhun and Chhetri castes, a handful of persons from Gurung, Rai, and non-Jãjarkot ethnic background. Therefore the ethnic makeup of the bazaar is much more diverse than that of the District as a whole. Jãjarkot's cropping patterns depend on altitude, access to water, type of soil, slope, latitude, and position toward the sun. In the high agricultural altitudes (over 2100 meters) corn, barley, potatoes, and wheat are the major crops. In the middle and low altitudes rice and millet complete the major crop list. Also important are mustard for oil pressing and pulses like black gram and cowpea for protein and soil improvement. Agricultural cash crops and commercial trade include tobacco, sugarcane, oilseeds, and ghee12. Jumli District pastoralists migrate seasonally into the interior of Jãjarkot District, where they buy ghee and wheat surplus. They carry supplies back to Jumlã and Dolpã and sell for a large profit, often 50% over purchase price in Jãjarkot. Jãjarkoti migrants to India also carry ghee for trading profit in Chinchu, a city on one of the migrant routes to the Nainatãl region of India. Rice is not an important crop for sale. Most land is unirrigated and supports a large variety of Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 17 crops (see Appendix). In terms of total production, Jãjarkot is rice deficit and subsidized through Nepal Food Corporation which has an office in Khalaÿgã. Within an hour's walk of the bazaar the average large animal livestock holding is about thirteen animals per household (water buffalo, cattle, goat and sheep). In villages over eight hours' walk from the bazaar the average holding is about eight animals. The difference in livestock holdings between rural and bazaar areas suggests that livestock are kept primarily for subsistence purposes in rural areas while in areas near the bazaar animals are used for both subsistence and for dairy sales to bazaar tea stalls and wealthier households. Animal tenure, or shepherding the livestock of a neighbor, is common in District Center satellite villages. Farmers with larger livestock holdings, especially Bãhuns, give their animals to shepherds who receive part of the dairy and meat or an agreed upon salary per season. Animal tenure is not generally practiced in areas over a day’s walk from the District Center, because production is for subsistence rather than for market, and livestock holdings are small. Forest products are important for subsidizing diet and making household implements. Some of the most important products derived from nearby forests include medicinals, bamboo, jute, barks, wild greens, wild honey, vegetable oil seeds (chiuri), berries, fodder, lumber, mushrooms, nuts, roots, religious leaves and plants, saponic nuts, spices, animal hunting and fishing (See Appendix for details on specific forest products). Kãmi ironsmiths scoop iron from local iron mines though iron also comes from terãi markets. From the above characteristics, we get a composite picture of Jãjarkot as varying along a geographical continuum of Bazaar - satellite villages - rural villages. Bazaar households are most affected by wage labor since they are the site of development offices and contract agreements for building improvements such as schools, roads, hospitals. Bazaar residents in general own few livestock, directly farm little land, are absentee landlords and patrons of artisans. High caste bazaar households maximize their opportunities for education and salaried employment in development offices. At the other end of the geographical continuum, rural residents tend to have much less formal education, own small but productive land holdings, rely on indigenous labor practices rather than wage labor, do migrant work for cash rather than salaried work. Rural households tend not to utilize development offices, including banks and 18 hospitals, but only rely instead on local healers (jhåkri, dãmi, jaiselu) and indigenous loan systems. Adjusting to Initial Fieldwork: A Place to Research Traveling to Jãjarkot District from Kathmandu, one boards an eighteenseater plane flying over the central hilly regions. Looking down, mountains and hills rise up in wave after wave with their sides planted in paddy fields near river beds. Terraced hills of millet and corn in the summer, and wheat and barley in the winter criss-cross along talus slopes below ridge tops thick (or sometimes thinly deforested) with pine forests. Terraced fields of grain rise almost to the tops of the hills, certainly to 2100 meters in height, in the pahãïi bhãg or "hills regions." Above about 2400 meters, in the lekãli bhãg one can make out thick forests capping the mountains and sometimes tiny paths where animals graze in the summertime. The plane lands in Dãng District and if the plane's circuit goes no farther, one walks two or three days out of Tulsipur, Dãng, through Lwãm and Jimãli villages in Salyan District and across the Bheri River into Jãjarkot District, a walk of 90 kilometers. In better economic times HMG Nepal sends the plane to Chaurjahari in Rukum District and one walks an hour through the flat fertile plain of Chaurjahari and across the Bheri River to begin the ascent to the administrative center of Jãjarkot District. The plain of Chaurjahari has a distinctly artisanal and administrative feeling to it. One walks past Bãdi caste men mending fishnets or spreading out tobacco pipes (chilim) for sale, gaily decorated in pinkpainted etchings of playing card symbols. Kuhmãle (potter) caste households also live along the road because, they say, the clay in this region is excellent for pottery making. Pots or gãgros of many shapes lay drying in the warm sunshine giving courtyards and porches smooth geometric simplicity. Nearby dry water taps are surrounded by dozens of blackened bronze and clay water pots, awaiting the hour when the taps are turned on and women gather to exchange information on latest events. At water taps women reign politically - though informally - powerful and 'water tap news' will be relayed to the rest of the household over dinner. Chaurjahari plain is also home of administrative offices, ranging from a Women's Development office to banks and schools. The most obvious development in the plain is the hydroelectric dam nearby which holds an electricity works (about 400 Kilowatts) which powers both the villages on the plain and reaches up to Jãjarkot's District Center. Electricity operates from sundown until about ten o'clock and allows for Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 19 reading at night and kitchen cooking in bright light rather than in smoky firelight. The Bheri River divides Jãjarkot from Rukum District; an old sturdy suspension bridge connects Jãjarkot and Rukum. Most travelers rest after crossing the suspension bridge which was built in the 1930's with local free labor (called begãr or hãnseri), elephants carrying cables from the terãi lowlands, and Scottish engineering expertise. At "Pul," a village wayside meaning "bridge," travelers drink tea among a myriad of flies and children, share a warm meal and cigarettes, and catch up on the latest news. Near the river one sees many fruit trees. An old farmer and his wife were one of the first in the region to use grafting techniques and have citrus nurseries with orange, lemon-lime (kãgati), and grapefruit along with tropical species such as mango, banana, and papaya saplings for sale. Since the ascent to the District Center is a quick one, from the River's elevation of about 600 meters to Khalaÿgã on the hilltop of about 2000 meters, one usually stops for tea and then aggressively climbs the remaining couple hours. Along the twisting uphill footpath, one walks through sãl [shorea robusta] and pine trees [salla; Pinus roxburghii] knotted as though avoiding the chewing onslaught of goats and cows. One sees paddy fields far below near the river, the fields bright green in July. Occasionally one meets travelers going down to Chaurjahari where they will board the plane for Nepalganj in the terãi or Kathmandu. The route from Chaurjahari to Jãjarkot's District Capital, called Khalaÿgã, is used by travelers from northerly Jumlã and Dolpã as well. Traders known as herders of sheep "trains" carry woven goods such as goat and sheep hair floor coverings (liu, pãkhi ), blankets (phere, rãdi) and ghiu (clarified butter) in wooden containers (theki). Porters carry forest products such as bitumen (silajit) and medicinals (hãtti jaru, bhulte, silaju) to Nepalganj. Administrative offices such as the Nepal Food Corporation organize ponies and porters to transport quintals of rice to Dolpã and Jumlã Districts (See Bishop, 1990 for an appendix of comprehensive data on goods traded in the Karnali Zone, including Jãjarkot). Jãjarkot communities stretch along a broad range of geographical micro-climates. Some far northern villages nestle between high hills in alpine forests where households grow rice on sunny slopes while corn and root crops mature on unirrigated rocky slopes. Middle villages in lower altitude deciduous forests specialize in collecting honey, or pressing chiuri oil (Indian butter tree; Madhuca butyracea or Bassia butyracea). Dairy farming is common and farmers send their children to not only watch the livestock but collect cinnamon bark (Cinnamomum tamala) and morel 20 mushrooms ( Nep: guchi chau). Hunters rely upon forests for pheasant, boar, deer, and other small game. Forests provide not only meat but dinner greens, more often than vegetable gardens in most rural villages. Raute people, sometimes billed as "the last hunter-gatherers of Nepal" forage through Jãjarkot in their search of monkey. The Raute live up to their reputation by refusing to interact with settled communities; they merely approach villagers to trade hand-crafted wooden boxes for grain. Jãjarkot district, holding 100,000 people, contains a wide variety of productive strategies and a large assortment of peoples such as Magar, nomadic Raute, shepherds from Jumlã and Dolpã in addition to a wide assortment of caste lineages. It seems likely, therefore, that Jãjarkotis engage in a broad overlapping assortment of labor practices, depending on their material and environmental conditions. The Research Life The theories one is taught in graduate school often seem a distant ideal to the reality of fieldwork. I experienced a mixed sense of this ideal and real while researching in the busy, constantly shifting productive environment of western Nepal, so remote from the urban centers of Kathmandu, Nepalganj, and Lucknow. The households in Jãjarkot District employ myriad productive strategies - foraging vegetables in the forests, herding water buffalo, contracting to build hospitals, roads, and irrigation canals. Jãjarkoti households are loosely linked to markets and few households produce grain for sale. Their labor relations reflect productive diversity through the use of village messengers, labor reciprocity, taking and giving loans of grain and labor rather than relying on a universal medium of exchange through money. I felt surprised at how little money was used by rural Jãjarkoti people. I was astounded by how often objects were bartered. I also had to learn to barter my services and assets so as to interact more naturally with rural households. My research assistant and I brought food when visiting rural villages (dried soybeans were a hit). I worked in farmers' fields though I was a slow and poor substitute for a Nepalese woman with years of experience. I "traded" jewelry, notebooks, pens, an insect net, kitchenware, and other households objects. I traded favors, let visitors sleep over, and cooked. I gave away a lot of photos and simple medicines. All this was part of my total capital, and since I didn't have grain or skilled labor, I had to barter as I did. It would be rude and inappropriate to pay a family, say, Rs. 50 for staying with them for a night. Instead, one creates more solid bonds by giving away presents, Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 21 cleaning the children's cuts, and requesting the host family to visit or stay over when they travel to the District Capital. The saying, roughly “bis rupyãko ek roti paundainã” (“can’t get a piece of bread for even twenty rupees”) reflects the uncommoditized nature of social relations in rural Jãjarkot. 13 The ubiquitous nature of barter in Jãjarkot is the result of several possibilities. Jãjarkotis experience inflation, a problem plaguing people throughout Nepal. Jãjarkotis use barter as a reaction to poverty; they earn little money and use barter to obtain essentials. Historically, in Jãjarkot money has infrequently been used; the current low level of cash flow is not astonishing, simply a historical fact (Humphery and Hugh-Jones, 1992; Orlove 1986). Jãjarkoti traders often prefer to barter rather than take cash and it may be a combined result of historical factors, a low regional cash flow, illiteracy, inflation, and overwhelming production for subsistence rather than market. Toward the end of my 1986-87 visit, my understandings of productive relations taken from others’ research often confronted the more complex realities of my own observations. I could see that group labor, simple labor reciprocity, and lending circles acted as tools for cooperation, i.e., they smoothed social relations. But I also noticed that indigenous labor practices functioned as forms of oppression. Casual labor (baure) is exploitative since the worker gets merely subsistence remittances. In practice reciprocal labor (parimã) sometimes benefits one party over another. The high caste large landowner may have little incentive to return an equal amount of labor to a less powerful labor partner. Also, loans can be exploitative. Collateral loans, grain loans, and indentured servitude all exact high interest rates. By August, 1990 I knew that indigenous labor practices are essential components of productive relations in Jãjarkot. Yet their significance was poorly appreciated by even Nepalese and foreign anthropologists. When I gave a summary of my field research project in 1990 to a group of men affiliated with the Center for Nepalese and Asian Studies (CNAS) they enthusiastically debated the roles of land tenancy, wage labor, and indentured servitude in Nepal. Yet one researcher summed up their feelings about my project, ‘But why do you study adhiyå (sharecropping)? It happens everywhere in Nepal!’ Most researchers in Nepal choose more esoteric or exotic topics. While topics such as shamanism and polyandry are certainly important to understanding Nepalese culture, equally important yet more mundane subjects such as sharecropping often get overlooked by anthropologists. Not only is understanding of indigenous labor practice essential to comprehension of 22 the logic of exchange and power in Nepalese society, the symbolic manifestations of labor relations can be profoundly moving as well. Perhaps there is no other long term experience quite as radical as change in language, dress, habits, everyday work routine, friendships, food, toilet, etc. during fieldwork. I arrived in Chaurjahari airstrip in midDecember, 1986 feeling decentered by immersion into a culture where few people spoke English and my senses of touch, sight, smell, and hearing were tainted with foreignness. As my field notes record, my encounter with other bideshis [foreigners] after getting off the plane didn't lessen the feeling of anomie: "Met a Tim Pritchard [from Britain] and a man from Holland [named] Gelner. They're working on drinking water projects and live here in Chaurjahari. They spoke Nepali and looked really rough. Reminded me of the oil workers in China that someone described to me. They were surprised that I am going to Jãjarkot." Sometime during that first day in Chaurjahari, my anomie wavered, though I couldn't honestly say it lessened. I started to compare local Nepalese with people I had known in the United States and this helped make people seem more common. For example, Mr. Paudel, the airport manager, reminded me of a botany lab technician from Grand Forks, North Dakota. I wasn't comfortable around the airport manager but the sense that he was a man doing a job just like people do everywhere was a comforting thought and helped me move from a self conscious state of mind to an inquisitive unselfconscious state. What isolation it was that first day in the gaun (rural area), before I knew how to even properly walk across the street to ask for tea! I didn't know if women, alone, often frequented tea stalls, but I suspected not. This was one of the times when being a single woman had distinct disadvantages. Consciousness of my gender was initially almost overwhelming. The airport manager watched me with great interest but probably because I was such an anomaly more than anything to do with gender. The question of whether my gender would permit me to do or say certain things was a continuing problem. I've heard a whole range of experiences from other female anthropologists, and I can only say that in Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 23 my experience, being female had some advantages, as in quickly being expected to perform cooking and women's work for the family I stayed with and thus being part of everyday disputes and gossip. But I found barriers and uncomfortable spots too, as when I visited political and development offices. Talk was often shallow and I initially received only ideal responses to information on land and labor issues. Whether this had something to do with my gender is uncertain and depended on the people with whom I interacted. When I interviewed a Rãstriyã Panchãyat (national political) representative, our first talk was completely on the level of ideal goals and accomplishments with no discussion of the intricacies of any development projects. When I asked him if he had any questions for me, anything he wanted to know about my study, he was most interested in why I was not married and what women in America are like. While he did not have a great interest in my line of research, I understood that from his perspective, many immediate questions had to be asked first: Why I was in Jãjarkot? How could a woman be so far from other family and American friends? And why did I want to study about Nepali farmers? During fieldwork I remember being acutely aware of my surroundings more than at any other time in my life. I felt an urgent need to understand everything if I was going to adjust reasonably well in Jãjarkot. I wanted to know how to be comfortable, to be unconscious of my extreme differences, and how to be involved in my new community's affairs enough to love and despise, to genuinely care about my neighbors. When I developed true friendships during my second period of research, I began to feel part of the community and to feel it was okay for me to continue to question strangers about their productive lives. Kamala Pun, from a little village in northern Jãjarkot, helped my work and adjustment immensely by pretending she understood what I was saying, by treating me like a sister that has to be taught everything, and by simply accepting me. Two of my research assistants from Jãjarkot, Dharma and Gyaneshwor, also came to be close friends. Their unhesitating acceptance that my research was important helped me when I had doubts. Dharma especially went out of his way to improve the research by redesigning questionnaires, walking to interviews that were farther than I wished to pursue, and continuing questions with rural folk when I was in the District Center. Both young men treated me like their big sister. If it had not been for a couple of meaningful friendships, I would not have continued my research in Jãjarkot. The months in Jãjarkot were filled with interviews and "walkabouts," into countryside outside the District Capital. I began with socio- 24 economic interviews and visits to various government offices. These interviews provided me with much of the quantitative data I have used for characterizing land and labor practices. The other purpose of initial surveying was to meet residents of Khalaÿgã and outlying villages and understand the immediate dynamics of their social organization. Quantitative data was useful to me in the first research period because I could gauge the importance and frequency of certain practices and simultaneously introduce myself and my research topic to a large assortment of people. The social reasons for surveying were important: surveying was a practical way to enter a new family’s home to develop rapport, to understand their material circumstances, to find out if we might become friends, and to gain an initial impression of a household's standing in the community. Chapter Organization Chapter Two presents a review of the literature specifically about indigenous labor practices. Since most readers are unfamiliar with indigenous labor practices, I begin the dissertation with a critique of writings about South Asian labor and save discussion of theoretical underpinnings of the dissertation for the following chapter. I begin by introducing the reader to a comparative classification of labor practices (D. Guillet 1980). This enables the reader to compare Nepalese labor practices with similar labor practices universally. Section One of Chapter Two reviews problems with previous research on jajmãni and patronage. Briefly, I critique previous views of jajmãni in terms of their exclusive forms within a system, the lack of attention to women, and the assumed degradation of jajmãni relations. Section Two of Chapter Two reviews selected South Asian research and mostly Nepalese literature pertaining to indigenous labor practices with special attention to hali (unfree labor) and jyãla (free/daily labor). I argue that unskilled agricultural labor has largely been marginalized by Western researchers in favor of the more "exotic" jajmãni. After reviewing Jan Breman's work in Gujarat (1974), I review discussions of unskilled labor in Nepal. In Section Three of Chapter Two I review descriptive writings about Nepalese labor exchange and gifts of labor. I conclude that most writings assume simple labor exchange and gifts of labor are egalitarian practices (Ishii 1982) rather than unequal exchanges without carefully observing the flow of labor between households. In Chapter Three I introduce three theoretical theses concerning the complexity of indigenous labor. First, I argue that non-capitalist labor and Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 25 production interacts, or articulates, with capitalist production, as one form might feed off another form. I introduce my theory of "Multiple Production Forms" (MPF) to describe the articulation between labor relations founded in patronage and capitalism. Previously researchers have used such concepts as feudalism (Stiller 1973; Bloch 1961), South Asian social formation (Klass 1991), and Asiatic Mode of Production (Bailey and Llobera 1981; Tsarong 1987) to characterize socioeconomic systems in South Asia. I conclude that while these depictions of South Asian socioeconomic systems give insights into productive logics, they unduly idealize productive relations and cannot explain real conditions with any preciseness. My goal in discussing labor is to look at the dialectic between material and symbolic manifestations of productive social relations. Chapter Three presents the view that production forms such as feudalism symbolically convey information which is recognizably distinct from other productive forms, such as capitalism. Notions of humor, for example, should be distinct in a capitalist system versus a feudal system. I find that in Jãjarkot, patronage as a production form uses specific symbolic "cues" which are distinct from the symbols of capitalism. Fredric Jameson (1981) calls these symbolic cues "ideologies of form." Throughout the dissertation I give examples of householders who convey their labor relations through verbal actions and non-verbal symbols which mark them as participating in a system of patronage. After discussing MPF , feudalism, and the Asian mode of production, Chapter Three addresses the question of equal exchange. Much previous anthropological literature takes for granted the assumption that two parties will continue a relationship based on some sort of reciprocity that is made equal or kept in stasis (e.g., Mauss 1925; Sahlins 1965; Humphery 1992). I argue that households exchange labor but do so in fundamentally unequal terms. These unequal exchanges reinforce extant class and caste 'social space’ (P. Bourdieu 1984). The writings of A. Emmanuel (1972) and C. Smith (1982) are especially pertinent to understanding the mechanics of unequal or asymmetrical exchange. Chapter Three concludes with a discussion of the role of caste and class stratification in Jãjarkot. I use an analysis which locates class position by land ownership, geographical location, education, and especially labor category. Chapter Four is a brief material history of the Jãjarkot region. I show here that while "feudal" may be an apt description on a level of comparison with other feudal societies of the past, the real relations and 26 forces in Jãjarkoti history (14th - 20th) are quite distinctive. Eschewing elitist historical renditions, I incorporate oral histories by low caste storytellers. I combine oral histories with documented written histories by educated elites. Both histories inform Jãjarkot labor history and highlight the working relationships between royalty and commoners. The Jãjarkot royal court labor categories - tax collectors, scribes, accountants, dispute settlers, artisanal servants, elephant drivers, village headmen - have nearly disappeared within this century. The King and Queen of Jãjarkot, for example, presently live in Kathmandu and are not residents of Jãjarkot. 14 Thus the social organization of indigenous labor, far from a static and traditional practice, has changed dramatically. Chapters Five, Six, and Seven comprise the core chapters of this dissertation because they focus on the actual indigenous labor practices in Jãjarkot. These chapters detail power relations of caste and class surrounding sharecropping (adhiyå), patronage, free and unfree labor (jãla, hali), labor reciprocity, group labor, and gifting (parimã, baure, sahayog). In Chapter Five I maintain that patronage is the dominant production form in Jãjarkot. I explore the mechanics of artisanal-patron relations (khalo), priest-benefactor relations (jajmãni), and loans (rin-din ). Part One of Chapter Five uses socioeconomic surveys to show a geographical variation in landholding patterns by caste strata. I maintain that due to extremely small landholdings, most low castes turn to skilled (jajmãni) and unskilled (baure, adhiyå, hali) laboring rather than small scale farming. Apparently, the jajmãni system cannot degrade until other viable work for near landless households emerges. For researchers interested in comparing data, I offer information on tailor and blacksmith piece rates, a caste stratified division of labor, and a comparison of economic information regarding skilled versus unskilled low caste households. In Part Two of Chapter Five I compare the lending and borrowing behavior of households. These households are classified as "Workers" (skilled and unskilled laborers and low castes) versus "Owners," (patrons, employers, landlords, high castes). I examine use of indigenous loans (bhandaki ko riÿ, sapati, byaj ko riÿ, anãj ko riÿ, kabul, udãro) and bank credit (Nepal Bank Limited, Agricultural Development Bank) by Workers and Owners. I conclude that Owners statistically tend to take Bank loans, to receive certain types of indigenous loans, and tend to give out indigenous loans. Workers tend to take only certain types of indigenous loans and tend not to participate in bank borrowing. Overall Jãjarkot's Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 27 lending scenario suggests a capitalist-oriented local elite drawing from introduced banking systems in order to augment their control over indigenous credit systems. Local low caste and class strata are depicted as tied securely to paternal indigenous lending systems and little connected in direct ways to introduced lending. This lending example in general is a good example of the interaction between production forms of capitalism and patronage. Chapter Six is devoted to understanding the worker's everyday social practice. I argue that workers often adapt to poorer quality lives than Non-workers by not following the elite’s normative rules. I show that low castes bend the rules of marriage. They practice remarriage, matrilocality, love marriage, and brideservice as digressions from high caste norms. In Section Two I depict quantitatively the lower quality of life of working households. I show that workers do much more unskilled labor than other households, they have lower standards of living, and they do not utilize development opportunities to the same extent as high castes. To conclude Chapter Six I present basic information about sharecropping and unskilled labor which other researchers may want for comparison with workers elsewhere. Chapter Seven explores the most egalitarian labor forms, reciprocal labor and gifts of labor. I stress two main points in this chapter. First, reciprocal labor and gifts of labor greatly increase the efficiency of agricultural production. More than simply two more alternatives in the network of labor practices, these informal labor practices are used often and at crucial times of the agricultural season. Second, labor reciprocity is always called “equal” but it can, and often is, an unequal relationship between partners. If one household has more social status than the other, the higher status household can persuade the weaker household to donate more labor days. I maintain that labor reciprocity is based on symmetry but non-egalitarian factors such as caste status or amount of land ownership affects the relationship. I conclude that labor reciprocity and gifting are adaptive management practices because they 1) provide much needed labor at critical times and 2) provide "subsistence-challenged" neighbors with good meals at exactly those periods when food resources are minimal. Larger landowners, however, gain valuable labor time from their land-poor neighbors under the guise of egalitarianism and cooperation. Chapter Eight, entitled ‘The Cultural Construction of Labor’, presents the culture of labor through stories and myth. As R. Williams wrote, our problem is one of how to make cultural history material 28 (1977:19). The symbols which display and help people to negotiate their labor relations are bound into symbolically significant items such as toy plows, flags, and handmade cloth, and persuasions in conversation. I maintain that symbolic actions encapsulated in words and gestures can actually influence labor relations. Through interviews with tenants, landowners, laborers, and artisans, I demonstrate that conversations can have definite influence on the shaping of economic and political labor relations. I present ethnographic examples of 1) a landowner who loses her land and takes supernatural revenge; 2) a ferryman who is enmeshed in many layers of labor relations with landlords and employers; and 3) a goldsmith who recounts a land grab and his reliance on the powerful patrons. Each of these ethnographic examples highlights the positions in social space of workers, landowners, and other labor relations. Finally, Chapter Nine wraps up some of the main issues and conclusions which I explored throughout the dissertation. First, I emphasize that the networks of labor relations are important to understanding the overall management of labor in Jãjarkot. Second, I suggest that our inability to culturally contextualize jajmãni may have been due to our elite perspectives, most often culled from Brãhmanical views of Hindu society and also to the Western scientific need to objectify social behavior. Third, I point out that even my own interpretations of Jãjarkoti society are touched by my own elite perspectives in that I have focused on patronage and hierarchical relationships for analysis rather than on the perspectives of low castes and workers. I conclude that a fuller understanding of the logic of exchange and power in Nepali society must incorporate a research approach grounded in the study of relationships and dialectic interactions rather than in a concretization or objectification of labor practice. Concluding Remarks In conclusion, I should write a few words about the language and methodology which I used during research. Almost all Jãjarkotis speak a dialect of standard Nepali, including the Magar ethnic groups who occupy much of the east and northern rural regions. Native speakers of Nepali in Kathmandu sometimes have difficulty understanding the vowel and consonant variations, the substitution of local words, and the truncated syntax structures or in reverse, the longer royal verb forms. For example, here is a proverb in the local dialect versus standard Nepali: Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 29 In Jãjarkot: jastã timra tiun taun, ustãi hãmra siun saun. In standard Nepali: jasto timile tiun tarkãri diyou, ustãi hãmile lugã siyoun. Both translate: ‘just as you give food, so we will sew the clothing.‘15 Literally a tailor says this about his or her patron in reference to their khal, or portion received for tailoring. Broadly speaking, one can say this proverb when they are working for another person in any capacity and wish to receive fair payment for their services. Although I took two years’ of Nepali classes during graduate studies, I needed research assistants for help with language problems. Quite often I understood words yet didn’t grasp the full meaning or more complicated implications. 16 My research assistants were indispensable. They translated, transcribed, helped with logistics, wrote up interviews, did research at government offices, accompanied me on trips as far away as India to interview Nepalese migrants, and pursued myriad small things like going about a village to tactfully scout for potential households to interview. Regarding research methods while I was in Jãjarkot, perhaps "planned spontaneity" is an appropriate description. I began the first period in 1986-87 with a household introductory survey of 30% of households in each neighborhood [tol] of Khalaÿgã, the District Center. Called the DCS or District Center Surveys, these forty household surveys were designed to introduce me to the people in the District Center and generate an initial set of data on kinship and work habits in the District Center. I collected a small amount of information in these surveys and they aren’t as helpful in understanding indigenous labor as later surveys. I revisited these same households again in 1993 and collected information on land, household demography, and production using the format of later surveys. The DCS are most helpful in understanding land ownership and production amounts. I also conducted qualitative interviews with about thirty government offices in Khalaÿgã, the District Center. I usually spoke with the chair or head manager of a particular office.17 The format of questions and parameters of all surveys are located in the dissertation appendix. In 1987 I conducted the next set of interviews in satellite villages of the District Center, up to four hours' walk away. These interviews are called the Peripheral Region Socioeconomic Surveys (PRS) and consist of 120 households in about twenty-five villages. The main categories during 30 these interviews were: 1) household demographic information, 2) land holdings, livestock, and agricultural production types, 3) indigenous and bank loans, 4) labor exchange practices, 5) development facilities/usage and political activity. On my return trip in 1989-90 I continued to focus on labor issues but constantly found that a productive lifestyle touches on many aspects of society such as religion and caste regulations. I conducted more open ended interviews in this second period in order to allow the Nepalese perspective to come through rather than my own categories of interest. I could speak and understand Nepali better after a year in residence and was better able to conduct open-ended interviews. I concentrated in the rural regions over one days’ walk from the District Center and ended up with 118 interviews comparable to the PRS. This set of interviews is called the Rural Region Socioeconomic Survey (RRS). The major difference between the PRS and the RRS is that the RRS was open ended, allowing participants to give a rambling account of their family members and landholdings which was appropriate and expected. The other survey I conducted was called the Labor Relations Survey (LRS). In it I non-randomly chose households from upper, middle, and lower socioeconomic levels from the District Center and four satellite villages. I tried to achieve a cross-sample of households from different caste backgrounds, different neighborhoods, and several households headed by women. For one month, my research assistant and I used a modified version of the Labor Time Survey in the Status of Women in Nepal series (Acharya and Bennett 1981). We recorded a total of 505 “moments” of labor activity among these households in which we dropped by and observed the activity of each family member. We recorded activities randomly from 6 A.M. to 7 P.M. My research is not founded on this last survey, since a labor time survey should be done for one year, but I used the method in order to estimate what categories of people (by gender, region, or caste) did certain types of work. Chapters Five through Seven employ the quantitative surveys. I found survey results most helpful when balanced with qualitative information such as interviews. Some of my most insightful information comes not from quantitative surveys but from turning on the tape recorder (with permission) after dinner or during excursions into the hills with Nepalese people that I met. I have about 79 interviews recorded lasting anywhere from five to 180 minutes. Only a handful have been transcribed and translated (sections from 20 interviews) and I use these to highlight ideas and for exegesis in the dissertation. Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 31 For Jãjarkoti society to be whole, many ties must hold the society together. Jajmãni patronage is one of many indigenous labor practices, some of which are cooperative and others exploitative. I began my research into Jãjarkot productive relations by searching for an understanding of the nature of Nepalese forms of cooperation. I have come to the conclusion that implicit within cooperation is conflict and competition. The study of indigenous labor relations is therefore a study in domination and subordination as much as a study of the complexity of labor. Nepalese society is not simply a dichotomy of capitalist, modern, developed (bikãsi) wage laborers stratified by social class; and feudal, traditional, backward, patron-clients stratified by social castes. Unfortunately the study of South Asian economies , and especially of jajmãni , is marred: “Modern economies are those which have undergone the ‘great transformation’, the rise of industrial, market capitalism in Western Europe and North America, in which market exchange has become the uniquely pervasive mode of economic integration. Traditional economies are those which have not undergone this transformation ... the fundamental divide is still between modern and traditional... The concept of the traditional economy has been generated as the negative of the modern by isolating and defining the traits which are not characteristic of modern economies, or rather those which are not susceptible to interpretation by Western economic theory (C. Fuller 1989:56). I attempt to remove the stereotypes of "non-Western labor relations" as inferior or subordinate by showing that indigenous labor practices are modern, responsive to social pressures, adaptable to money exchanges, adaptable to changes in social caste and class, and resilient in that they are not decaying through contact with full blown capitalist economies. = ==================================================== Notes to Chapter On e 32 1 Definitional note on the difference between "wage" in capitalist and paternal production forms: A wage is recompense for energy expended to create an object of value. From the owner of the means of production the worker receives cash, grain, or any other recompense (a wage) in exchange for energy expended and the creation of value. The owner pays a wage for the energy expended, the creation of value (a product), and usually surplus value. This constitutes exploitation, though not necessarily in a negative sense, of the worker for creating more value and receiving less wage. The crucial difference between capitalist and paternal wage relationships is one of subsistence to the worker. In a paternal relationship the worker is paid according to the grain and money and any other recompense which will sustain the worker and/or household. In a capitalist relationship the recompense is negotiated according the relative leverage powers of the workers versus the owners. In a capitalist wage relationship the worker may accumulate a surplus but in the paternal relationship the worker will not accumulate a surplus through his relationship with the owner of the means of production. 2 The underlying ideology of "development" or in Nepali, bikãs or sudhãr (improvement) contains a large constellation of meanings. For discussions of the semiotics of development see L. Stone 1989; D. Bista 1991; S. Pigg (in press). A favorite joke in Nepal is that of a poor destitute man waving from the ditch at a development worker who passes by. The development worker stops and the man cries out, "Help me sir! I am the victim of development!" 3 Note that wage labor is not necessarily related to a capitalist system of political economy. The Arthãsastrã, for example, discusses wages in Kautilyan society circa 4th century B. C. - A. D. 150 (Rangarajan 1992). 4 Jãri, contrary to my observations, has been described as a form of exploitation of women (INSEC 1992). Remarriage is not well researched in Nepal or India. There could be examples of female remarriage as an exploitative practice, though I have not witnessed remarriage in an exploitative capacity. 5 In Jãjarkoë the following indigenous lending is common: simple loans (sapati), collateral loans (bandhãki ko riÿ), grain loans (anãjko riÿ), indentured service loans (kabul), shop credit (udãro), and interest loans (byãjko riÿ). 6 For a partial bibliography of reading on jajmãni , see especially Fuller 1989; Kolenda 1967; Miller 1986; Mitchie 1981; Raheja 1988b; Steen 1986. 7 Lewis and Barnouw (1967) follow with an important footnote citing a few other notable works dealing with “the relationship between caste and economics,” especially S.S. Nehru 1932; Kumar Goshal 1944; O.C. Cox 1948. 8 Brahmin women do auxilary priestly tasks such as gathering materials for painting icons, collecting payments, and reading holy texts during holy days. Jana Fortier 1995 Beyond Jajmani: The complexity of indigenous labor relations in western Nepal. PhD Diss., UW-Madison. 33 9 Breman specifically refers to Cohn, 1955; Gough, 1960; Gould 1964; and Harper 1959. The same can be said for most writings about jajmãni . 10 See Appendix for all survey parameters. 11 I did ask much household information, including names, ages, and genders of all household members in the Rural Region Survey (N=118 households); Peripheral Region Survey (N = 118 households) and District Center Survey (N = 40 households). In these surveys I noticed perhaps an even greater disparity of male to female survey population. Possiblities for an imbalanced ratio of male to female include 1) female benign neglect; 2) female infanticide, 3) surveyed household heads, usually male, failed to recall some female relatives in the household; 4) a greater number of men have migrated to India for a number of years and have failed to return to Jajarkot. The number of Jajarkoti men in HMG service outside of Jajarkot is small. Finally, the survey from which the male-female ratios is taken (Aryal 1982) is probably not accurate given difficulty in collecting demographic data in Nepal. 12 By "cash crop and commercial trade" I infer people who purposely produce above subsistence amounts of something to suppliment their incomes. Tobacco sales might mean selling up to about five pounds at one time, though I never witnessed so much being sold. People sell sugarcane at fairs to children. Households might sell up to ten tins of oilseeds (Rs. 60 x 10 tins = Rs. 600) to traders from Jumla or Dolpa. Farmers who need cash will sell one or two tins of ghee (total Rs. 200) maybe once or twice a year. I would not say such sales hook Jajarkoti people into a global market. The small but illegal trade in cannibis and musk oil would be two products which hook Jajarkot economy into global markets. 13 This saying, multivocalic as are all proverbs, also alludes to another idea. People who won't trade and especially won't even give a little of their grain to strangers are backward, suspicious, inbred, and best avoided. Also, this does not refer to inflation. A full meal still costs only about Rs. 5 - 10 in areas near the airport, but regardless, there are no places which sell meals in western Nepal. 14 The present King of Jajarkot keeps his title but almost none of the previous benefits of a feudal kingship such as tax collection and adjudication of his subjects. Jajarkot is one of three remaining kingdoms within the greater kingdom of Nepal, to whom the Jajarkot Kingdom pays a Rupees 701 tithe of acknowledgement when kings pass on their Jãjarkoëi crown. 15 I am not too concerned with caste ranking and food symbolism in this instance except to mention that exchanges of food for service are correctly called by M. Marriott the ‘food of gifts’, i.e., raw foods immune from pollution (1968; see also Dumont 1966:83-90). 16 During one memorable interview, the oldest man in the village, reportedly 108 years’ old, told me in quavering village Nepali about how his land had been eaten up [khãyo] by the constantly expanding Bheri River. I believed he was talking about eating food and responded, “Oh, how good!” [kasto rãmro]! 34 17 A partial listing of offices in 1989-90. Exact Office titles are omitted. 1. Forestry Office; 2. Agricultural Development Office; 3. Courthouse; 4. Agricultural Development Bank; 5. Nepal Bank Limited; 6. Cooperative Office; 7. Red Cross; 8. Weaving Cooperative; 9. Sports Office; 10. Post Office; 11. Telegraph Office; 12. District Office; 13. Village Panchayat Office; 14. National Panchayat Representative; 15. Police Office; 16. Education Office; 17. Women’s Development Group; 18. Elderly Political Representative; 19. Farmer’s Political Representative; 20. Veternary Office; 21. Hospital; 22. Cooperative Distribution Centre; 23. Nepal Food Corporation local office; 24. Water Distribution Office. 51 2 OTHER VOICES ON INDIGENOUS LABOR RELATIONS This chapter concerns what other researchers have written and thought about jajmãni patronage, bonded labor, casual labor, labor reciprocity, and gifts of labor. I give most attention to research done in Nepal, specifically the works of B. Bishop, H. Blustain, L. Caplan, P. Caplan, H. Ishii, N. Levine, P. Prindle, and M. C. Regmi. Since much writing has been done on the subject of patronage in India, I favor reviewing works which specifically address patronage over ethnographies and reports with short references to jajmãni. In Part One of this chapter, I present a comparative classification of indigenous labor practices (Guillet 1980). Guillet's classification, developed out of fieldwork in Peru, is accurate cross-culturally, though there exists much local variation in specific contexts, and there is variation from Guillet’s classification in the management of labor in Nepal. Guillet’s work is meant to orientate and introduce the reader to Nepalese indigenous labor practices through a comparison with English terms of labor recruitment. In Part Two of this chapter I examine research writings on jajmãni and khalo in four respects. First, I review the early writings, and argue that pioneering studies largely ignored the overall context of which jajmãni was a part. Second, I examine women’s roles in research writing on jajmãni and indigenous labor practices in general. I find that even when women are actively involved in jajmãni relations, both male and female researchers omit attention to women's activities. There are no substantive references to the jajmãni roles of women in almost all the literature on the management of labor in South Asia. Third, I discuss degradation theories surrounding jajmãni. It seems that since jajmãni became a subject of intense interest to mainly Western anthropologists, they assumed paternal jajmãni would wither when confronted with "modern" capital intensive styles of labor recruitment. My research shows this not to be 52 the case. To conclude the outline of writings concerning jajmãni, I review information on payments and exchange rules in patronage. I find that researchers attempted to quantify payments and wages but found this to be a difficult task. The political and symbolic obligations of jajmãni are difficult to quantify and yet are integral aspects of payment. Most researchers could not account for these parts of the economic relationship and thus distorted the real economic relationships involved. Part Three of this chapter reviews literature on bonded and free labor forms, focusing i on conditions in Nepal. Special attention is directed to writings which address the role of bonded and free labor in the management of labor. In writing about hali, researchers tended to mistakenly conflate jajmãni and hali obligations. The practices are entirely distinct, yet given the fine networks of obligations between landowners and workers, researchers tended to blur their descriptions of bonded labor and jajmãni (e.g. Prindle 1977). Second, few researchers address the question of unequal exchange in hali (bonded labor) and khalo (artisanal patronage). The nature of inequalities should be an important part of studying labor relations because the asymmetry of landowner-tenant relations is often mitigated. The whole notion of “adha” (half, equal shares), which forms the root of the tenant arrangement called adhiyå, implies that the arrangement is fair between the parties. Part Four of this chapter compares descriptions of reciprocal labor and gifts of labor with extant conditions in Jãjarkoë District. There is little written about these labor forms specifically for Nepal, though a large literature exists on gift exchange in general. I focus on the few works devoted to information on Nepãli labor exchanges. Overall I scrutinize writings with the assumption that jajmãni is one small part in a larger system for managing productive social relations. I critique other writings in light of this supposition. Secondly, I examine writings for whether they acknowledge power differences between castes, classes, or labor partners. I conclude that more research writings need to delve 53 into the asymmetrical relations in bonded labor, jajmãni, gifts of labor, and other non-capitalist labor management strategies. A Cross-Cultural View of Labor Recruitment D. Guillet (1980), using a template from C. Erasmus (1956), outlined labor recruitment forms which correlate to many forms of labor in Nepal. He broke labor recruitment down into five forms: 1) contractual labor in which a voluntary agreement to work for a given amount of time can be remunerated in either cash or kind; 2) reciprocal labor which is subdivided into either exchange labor or festive labor; 3) custodial labor which refers to an obligation to work due to the pressure of political or other powerful authorities; 4) gift or donated labor; and 5) familial labor. Figure 2.4 Categories of Labor Cross-Culturally and within Jãjarkoë District Forms of Labor Recruitment (D. Guillet) Name of Labor Form in Jãjarkoë 1. Contractual 2. Reciprocal a. exchange labor b. festive labor khalo , jajmãni, hali, adhiyå, jãla, kut* ii parmã (parimã, parimo) baure, kãm gardna joù, nogãr* 3. Custodial a. Household b. State kamãra-kamãri, kãm garaune iii sramadhan, begãr, hanseri 4. Gift sahayog, madat 5. Familial . suhasthi** *a named labor practice common in Nepal but not practiced in Jãjarkoë **a Sanskrit term, archaic and not commonly used Guillet’s categorical schema is helpful because it provides a framework in which to consider the organization of Nepalese labor practices. Previous discussions of the function and structure of 54 isolated labor forms in Nepal (Ishii 1982 and Messerschmidt 1981) unduly focus on one set of relations, forgetting the network of marginalized labor practices. The jajmãni literature is a primary example in which researchers focused on one set of contractual labor relations, ignoring the network of other labor practices which inform jajmãni relations. Guillet’s classification does not fit all of Jãjarkoë labor practices, however. Sahayog, for example, is glossed as a gift of labor. In Jãjarkoë sahayog usually refers to one person going to a neighbor to help another with some domestic duty such as threshing grain with no expectation of remuneration. Yet in Magar villages in northern Jãjarkoë people use sahayog as group work on each others’ fields, a meaning Guillet would gloss as 'festive labor'. Also, Bãhun households sometimes use the term sahayog as dãn, donations for religious merit which consist of money, cloth, food, etc. Baure, casual labor, also marginally falls into categories of either reciprocal or custodial labor. When high castes call low castes for work the exchange is usually unilateral and custodial. When people work for someone of the same caste echelon they likely will return the labor, making the baure relationship reciprocal. Thus while Guillet‘s categories are heuristic cross-culturally, overlap persists in Nepal due to differences in social organization based on caste. Finally, Guillet's category 'contractual labor' is not accurate enough in distinguishing various types of Nepalese labor. "Contractual labor" as a category includes sharecropping (adhiyå), renting land (kuë), bonded labor (hali), artisanal service (khalo), priestly service (jajmãni), and daily labor (jãla). As M. Foucault points out (1977:22), where we draw theoretical lines of division says more about ourselves than about the phenomena described: “[familiar] divisions... are always themselves reflexive categories, principles of classification, normative rules, institutionalized types... they are not intrinsic, autochthones, and universally recognizable characteristics.” Guillet's divisions of labor recruitment help the uninitiated reader understand Jãjarkoëi labor. 55 Yet artificial boundaries - contractual, reciprocal, custodial, etc. - are not real to local households. Nepalese labor practices stretch their definitional boundaries, becoming redefined in actual practice and over time. Householders recruit labor for particular agricultural needs by tailoring their labor management practices. Contractual Labor Recruitment: jajmãni, khalo, and variations To operationalize jajmãni, one should know that the character and definition of this broad term changes over time and geographical space. In Jãjarkoë the term jajmãni describes the hereditary ritual and economic relationship between a Bãhun priest's household and his patrons' households, of which there can be over a hundred, throughout a region. In literature concerning India, jajmãni refers to a set or system of hereditary social, economic, and ritual relationships, or “rights and obligations,” between service specialists of all sorts (singers, drummers, washers, tailors, priests, ironsmiths, etc.) and the landowning patrons who paid a portion of their grain harvests in lieu of services. In Jãjarkoë the artisan - farmer relationship is not called jajmãni, but is known as khalo. From a Western economic standpoint, one may describe both jajmãni and khalo as having practitioners who do skilled labor. In contrast, agricultural labor performed iv by plowmen (haliyã) and female planters (roparni ) would be known as unskilled labor. In the following discussion I review works from pan-India and I therefore employ the term jajmãni as a generalization. I use the Nepalese term khalo when citing a particular reference from areas where this term is used. Pioneering Studies of Jajmãni as a "System" The most common misconception of early twentieth century writings about jajmãni practices was that it was a self-contained, bounded system. Charlotte Wiser (1930) and Ben Wiser (1936), Protestant missionaries, coined the misnomer jajmãni “system” in their books, Behind Mud Walls (1930) and The Hindu Jajmãni System (1936). The practice of receiving gifts and 56 grain from an artisan’s jajmãn is not actually a system in itself but is related intimately to other practices such as land tenure, free and bonded labor, cash and kind loans, and migration. Jajmãni is, I argue, one aspect of many inter-related labor relationships, a dominant theme in the caste proscribed management of indigenous labor. Although artificially bounding jajmãni and omitting other related labor relations, the Wisers’ work was nevertheless pioneering in description. They detailed the first empirical accounts of jajmãni. English legal court proceedings contained the only previously detailed v discussions of the economic aspects of caste relations (Wiser 1936:xxxvi). Hindu economic treatises like the Law of Manu (Bühler 1886) and the Arthashastra (Rangarajan 1992) essentially did not deal with untouchables and therefore referred to artisan caste duties in major aspects but were not explicit. Unfairly, the Wiser‘s work acquired a reputation for being overly benevolent, integrative or blindly stressing the benefits of the jajmãni system over its exploitative aspects (Beidelman 1959). In such critiques reviewers like Beidelman completely overlooked Charlotte Wiser’s book as a piece of critical writing. C. Wiser’s book was systematic, interrelational, and it also addressed conflict between castes in a sympathetic yet honest manner. Witness, for example an excerpt of Charlotte Wiser paraphrasing a high caste person: ‘The chamars[leatherworkers] have tried to raise themselves higher by changing their name to jadav! As long as they were chamars everyone associated them with chamre-hides. Their special duty in the village remains the skinning of dead animals, and because of this defiling work, we keep them down below caste lines’. (1963 (1930):226). As missionaries, the Wisers were especially concerned with the integrative aspects of Hindu society and jajmãni but not to the point of ignoring caste conflict. By calling the relationship between artisan and patron “the jajmãni system,” the practice lost any emphasis on local expressions and variations, a trend closely linked to the 57 Chicago school which emphasized a “Big Tradition - Little Tradition” view of Hindu cultural practice (R. Miller 1966). Hindu social laws gleaned from Brãhmanical written scripts, the Big Tradition was actually the dominant viewpoint of researchers while local traditions were largely ignored, underrepresented, and merely cited for comparative purposes with the great Hindu traditions (M. Marriott 1955). Whatever the local name for a patron-artisan relationship, all Western or non-South Asian language speakers came to associate variations of patronartisanship with the ideals of jajmãni set out in Wiser and other early interpretations (Cohn 1955; Gould 1959; Harper 1959; Gough 1958). One exception is an essay by Morris Opler and Rudra Datt Singh (1948). They describe the “division of labor” in Singh’s home village with careful accounting to the responsibilities of each of the 26 jãt is yet never use the term “jajmãni system”: Many of the work arrangements of the village are regulated by the purjan-jajmãn or hereditary workman-customer relationship. Purjans are castes of workmen or servants who are called upon to provide certain services because of an understanding, lasting over many generations, between the families involved. (1948:494-95). In Jãjarkoë jajmãni is distinguished from the Great Tradition Sanskritic ideal in several ways. The term jajmãni applies only to the relationship of priests to their patrons. Other contractual obligations between artisans (tailors, ironsmiths, singers, etc.) and patrons are called khalo. Artisans take grain, sometimes literally from the threshing floor of their patron and call this their khal. Priests receive a sida or portion of the patron's household goods. The khal or portion allowed to artisans and the sida to Bãhuns are only one of many fundamental differences. In addition, the socioeconomic circumstances, laws, and landholding sizes of Jãjarkoëi households differ from those described by the Wisers or other early writers. I advocate that researchers in Nepal compare khalo (also known as kumãune, bãli, and bista) to the Hindu ideal of jajmãni but clearly distinguish Nepalese variations. 58 In more recent writings which may also turn out to be pioneering, jajmãni has been reexamined as not a system but related to a larger political-economy. D. Miller (1986:535) asserts that studies of jajmãni are dogged by Western scientific notions of the closed artificial concept of system: “The objective of this paper is to address the nature of the jajmãni system; this concern implies a defense of the proposition that such a system exists....” While he believes that the etic use of “jajmãni system“ helps researchers to identify relationships between similarities of patron-artisanship, he advocates examination of local expressions within a jajmãni -like practice as more rewarding. Another writer, A. Good (1982), wisely, opposes using the term jajmãni in places where it is not used locally. It may have meanings which vary from the ideal first described by the Wisers. Following Good and D. Miller, I find that in Jãjarkoë jajmãni should be defined as particular to the priest - patron relationship. Khalo or other local names should be stressed in research writings because they are a more accurate rendering of local circumstances. Second, the role of jajmãni should be examined as part of a total complex which includes other labor practices and relationships. This holistic approach of positioning jajmãni within a network of labor practices precludes the use of a false systemic framework. The Missing Account of Women's Roles in Jajmãni My work on women’s roles in jajmãni and labor recruitment helps to balance previous androcentric research reporting on labor relations. The study of the kula by B. Malinowski (1965) is a classic example of primarily men’s exchange taken as a case study of all Trobriand exchange. He wrote at length on male viewpoints but only until A. Weiner (1976) researched the female vantage were we able to get a rounded and deeper understanding of exchange relations. Like myself, Weiner was surprised to find little or no information on the role and actions of women in exchange rituals: 59 I looked in Malinowski's accounts [and]...failed to find information concerning women's wealth of skirts and bundles and the particular events of the day. My original research proposal was not concerned with the study of women, but from that first day I knew that women were engaged in something of importance that apparently had escaped Malinowski's observations. (1976:78) In the major writings addressed principally toward jajmãni (about 25 works) there is scant attention paid to women’s work, even in writings by women (Epstein 1962; 1967; 1971; Gough 1960; Kolenda 1967; Benson 1976). Again Charlotte Wiser’s Behind Mud Walls (1930) is the only ethnographic text to provide a clear empirical rendering of women’s roles in jajmãni. For example, after describing high caste women’s influences, she notes untouchable women’s influences: There are other women whose influence counts in the village, women who circulate through courtyards other than their own... among them are the kaharins who are employed to carry water from wells to the houses where the women observe purdah; the kachhins who go into larger farm households to help with the splitting of pulses and grinding of grains; the wife of the washerman who collects and delivers clothes; and the sweeper women who go into most of the high-caste households, to clean privies and drains (1963 (1930]:84). Works which omit the role of women in jajmãni, for instance Gould (1964) which I will discuss shortly, possibly do not see women’s work as “economic.” Female workers, i.e., barberesses, cowherdesses, dairywomen, midwives (a purely female service category), scavengers and sweepers, etc., constitute half of Gould’s research population but nowhere does he, or almost all other writers on jajmãni, examine women as workers. Janet Benson (1976:248), for example, concludes that “as a result [of recent village changes], the junior set of [barber] brothers complain that the other two are serving most of the households in the village...” yet she neglects to mention what the female barber caste members are doing. Are they also complaining? Are 60 they working as masseuses or nail cutters, two common female barber occupations? What is their caste work? At least Charlotte Wiser’s writing gives a small clue: Most influential among them [women] ...is the barber’s wife. While she massages a new mother or helps anoint a bridegroom with oil, she chooses appropriate bits from her store of gossip and philosophy....The attitude of this worldly-wise lady has weight among her wall-bound clients [women in purdah], and we have found her support exceedingly worthwhile. (1963 (1930):84). Unfortunately nowhere in jajmãni literature up to 1990 is there an empirical or “economic” accounting of payments to barber women, sweeper women, midwives, tailoring women, etc. or of their relationships with their patrons. All previous studies of the jajmãni system substantively ignore the fact that males and females have a gendered division of labor. Peter Prindle, working in eastern Nepal, describes the essential [sic] jajmãni relationship as one in which “a Bhujel man is employed on an annual basis by a Brãhman to carry out all his plowing needs.” (1977:291). Besides the fact that Prindle has conflated hali with jajmãni, he has ignored the fact that women too have jajmãni relationships. We assume that Bhujel women do domestic and field labor for the same Brãhman household but we have no way of knowing if this is indeed true. Harvey Blustain (1984) examines a north-central Nepalese community off the main highway near Pokhara in which bãli (jajmãni) occurs. Men from Kãmi households smith iron but the women's jajmãni work is unknown. Almost all Damãi families sew but again Damãi women‘s roles are unknown. The Damãis also act as village musicians but, whether women sing and dance is unknown. Women are not included in Blustain’s analysis: "For while most sons employ the same Damãi or Kãmi as their fathers (and conversely, most Damãi and Kãmi sons work for the same patrons as had their fathers), a small but significant amount of clientchangings can occur”(1984:111). Even in critical reviews, such as Kathleen Gough's of Beidelman's book (1960), Gough and the writers she reviews fail to see that only men's work is 61 being discussed and that women have intrinsically different relations to their patrons because of the gendered division of labor. Anthropological analyses of jajmãni are bereft of fuller dimensions due to omissions concerning women’s roles. As Joan W. Scott wrote, “In attending to the economic bases for the artisans’ politics, historians have neglected other dimensions of their discourse, those having to do with gender and the family.” (1988:93). Women's roles in the management of indigenous labor is an essential part of this dissertation. For the reader to fully understand the exigencies of reciprocal labor, patronage, networks of labor recruitment, how women solicit gift labor for timely agricultural operations, and other agricultural decisions, researchers must offer their readers complete information on women's work. In Nepal, women do more labor than men, up to four hours per day more according to one report (Acharya and Bennett 1981). Degradation Theories of Jajmãni Insisting that local labor practices cannot be as efficient as capitalist wage labor, degradation theories of jajmãni obscure our understanding of local labor practice. Purveyors of degradation theories stereotype indigenous labor management forms as backward, traditional, and unable to create agricultural surpluses. Since nearly every agriculturist in Jãjarkoë employs several indigenous labor management strategies, the degradationist theories are not only incorrect, they may carry hegemonic messages promoting capitalism as well. The theory that jajmãni “systems” degrade over time through contact with commercial practices has been very popular in jajmãni literature. The degradational literature usually describes jajmãni as feudal and exploitative. Villages using jajmãni are summarized as either not yet degrading due to isolation from capitalism (M.N. Srinivas 1955) or quickly degrading due to modernization (K. Gough 1955). In rare exceptions, such as in E. Leach (1960), jajmãni relations are described as a form of mutual symbiosis with little reference to cultural change. vi 62 In this section I present examples of degradation theories by Gould (1964), Epstein (1962), and Blustain (1984) who review writings about jajmãni. Gould (1964) presented jajmãni as a survival social relationship utilizing ritual purity/pollution, land ownership, and tagadãri twice born status to divide society into givers and takers. This is a Western influenced belief in the inherent demise of the jajmãni system: “It is conceivable that then [unstated point in the past] a landed aristocracy with elite caste pedigrees were exclusively jajmãn, whereas specialists, excepting Bãhuns, were landless artisans and menials of middle and low caste antecedents.” (1964:37). Besides flying in the face of archaeological evidence (Adhikary 1988; Stein 1980), there are several problems with Gould’s conclusions. First, he admits that he has no idea of what caste obligations actually were in the unstated past. Second, no one has researched the historical vii roots of jajmãni , and historians at present do not know the extent of degradation or actual relations of change in jajmãni . Gould and others interested in jajmãni used a European-based feudal conception of jajmãni which partially explains their incorrect tendency to put jajmãni into a past-oriented framework. In the 1940-50’s, writers referred to the feudal style of jajmãni relations, especially when relations involved a dominant king/warrior Kshatriya or Rajput caste strata rather than priestly Bãhun landlords. Hitchcock refers to the “martial” style of jajmãni; Blunt to semifeudal styles; Hutton, Beidelman, Gould, and Hocart together to feudal styles when they described jajmãni (examples from Strayer and Coulborn 1956:6). Strayer and Coulborn, who noticed this Eurocentric theoretical perspective, believed that feudal society must be based on fiefs as well as a number of other key components of feudalism. Such feudal components are absent in Nepal which leads one to discount the thesis that jajmãni shall degrade because it is part of an outmoded feudal system. The myth of constant degradation deserves closer attention because it is related to the politics of development. In writing about the state of development, S. Epstein (1962) 63 characterizes jajmãni as constantly degrading, traditional, and incompatible with modernity. She describes villages as more ‘developed’ which evince commercialization, increased social stratification, increased dispersion of economic ties, increased economic mobility, loss of elders' hereditary roles in Panchãyat politics, and loss of ritual relations between households (jajmãni) though functionary ritual relations are still intact including jajmãni. She deals explicitly with changes in irrigation and tractor use and advocates that villagers maximize their work efforts (”capitalist” strategy) rather than minimize their losses (”pre-capitalist” strategy). Her work is part of the historically popular mini-max economic development theories prevalent before 1975. Major donor agencies - USAID, World Bank, UNDP - wished to revolutionize technologies, build irrigation projects, integrate rural development projects, and continue the “green revolution.” Epstein‘s work, apparently very applicable to such research and development efforts, viewed jajmãni as degrading only to be replaced by Eurocentric ideals of democratic capitalist work relations. As I argue in later chapters, jajmãni relations have lessened in urban settings, but they were probably little used in urban settings historically. In rural settings with less capital intensive farming, jajmãni relationships probably continue to be efficient means of exchanging services and grain. Epstein’s comparison of capital versus caste driven economic practices contributed an unusual and important facet to understanding jajmãni . Until her writings there were no effective insights into impacts of intensive capitalization on the jajmãni “system.” Unfortunately, she concludes with a moral opinion: "A prescribed hereditary system of rights and duties [jajmãni] ...is a mark of a stagnant rather than a developing economy." Her view of subsistence-oriented farmers draws false generalizations about all India: In a country such as India, with low soil fertility and little and/or irregular rainfall, there are usually great fluctuations in harvests...If my analysis of traditional Indian peasant economies is valid...we may find that many societies with a low level of technological knowledge and ...inability to control their 64 environment tend to distribute produce in a standard pattern equally in bad as in good seasons. (1971:118-119) While Epstein's work focused on central India, her generalizations were meant to cover the geographical regions, including Nepal, where households practiced jajmãni. Soil fertility and rainfall patterns vary enormously across India which is Epstein's most salient over generalization. More importantly, she fails to recognize complexities of taxation that far from 'leveling' the distribution of production, further aggravate economic and political stratification. Most importantly for this dissertation's focus, social hierarchies are based on caste, but also class distinctions, which Epstein completely overlooks in stating reasons for how produce gets distributed. Unequal distribution of production according to caste and class imperatives is often completely overlooked by Westerners and avoided by Indian researchers. These are an important basis of social inequality in India. The Rãjãs, Zamindãrs, Brãhman landlords, Kshatriyã officers of the court have all maintained their positions by distribution of produce not in a "standard pattern" which equalized profits, but in a pattern which maintained a privileged wealthy upper class. Harvey Blustain‘s (1984) work represents another degradation position of jajmãni focused upon north-central Nepal. He wrote a review of social change in jajmãni using an example from his own research and that of four authors who address jajmãni relations over time in Nepal (Lionel Caplan, Peter Prindle, David Seddon with P. Blaikie and J. Cameron, and Alan MacFarlane). Blustain contends that while jajmãni is hierarchical and exploitative, low castes would suffer from termination of the traditional productive relationship. Blustain’s own research site is unrepresentational since more than a third of the village is Muslim, normally a rare ethnic group in north central Nepal. But his choices of research to review are equally unrepresentational of jajmãni relations. Blustain’s reviews of Seddon et al.: ...general tendencies emerged clearly [in Seddon et al’s survey]: an overall reduction in the number of peasant households involved in the bista system...reflecting the increasing 65 importance of 'market' considerations in relations between peasants and rural artisans." (1984:115 quoting Seddon et al. 1979:84). This statement tells us little about change in jajmãni (called bista in north central Nepal). Though market relations are becoming increasingly important, Seddon et al.’s study doesn’t apply to much of Nepal. It studied effects on villages near roadheads where new highways were being built to Pokhara. Blustain should have omitted Seddon et al.‘s study since it treated the effects of roadways and examined no aspects of Nepalese jajmãni relations in detail. Blustain next cites MacFarlane who wrote Resources and Population. MacFarlane‘s study focused on pressures of population on resources among Gurung in north central Nepal. His work also lacks any substantive data for evaluating jajmãni relations in Nepal. MacFarlane’s primary conclusions relating to jajmãni are that low castes own little land (nothing new) and imports could usurp locally made artisan products (probably). Yet, according to Macfarlane, bãli (jajmãni) payments continued to be made in many Gurung Artisan relations, a point which challenges degradation theories. Blustain turns to Peter Prindle’s “The Jajmãni System: A Nepalese Example,” a short article for his third review of change in jajmãni in Nepal. Prindle’s treatment of Brãhmanviii Bhujel relations begins by confusing ideals of jajmãni with hali (1977:291): In brief, the Brãhman-Bhujel jajmãni bond was a relatively permanent one while, at the same time, it was flexible in that payment was proportional to the labor provided [cites no empirical data]. More specifically, payment was determined according to the number of days it would take to plow a person’s land...Payment was made in the form of a small grant of cultivable land or an equivalent amount of grain. It would be interesting to find out if Brãhman patrons give loans to Bhujel plowmen. If this true, then a form of bonded labor known in India as hali is more descriptive of the Brãhman Bhujel relationship. If loan giving/taking is not a bonding mechanism, then Prindle’s case is still unusual. First, Bhujels are not untouchables. They are a touchable, clean matwãli 66 (drinking) caste, an ethnic group interacting with Brãhmans like Rai and Limbu ethnic groups in the region. The Bhujel would have no caste-proscribed reason to plow for Brãhmans. The Bhujel themselves employ low caste tailors and ironsmiths using patron-client ties. Prindle should have discussed the relationship between tailors, ironsmiths and the Brãhman and Bhujels. Normally service castes which take bãli or khalo payment are low castes, (Brãhmans receive payment called sida). Second, the village demographic make-up is unusual: Brãhman(256 households), Bhujel(90 households), plus others (unstated number of households). Bhujels reportedly perform no non-agricultural village functions such as singing, dancing, blessing water vessels, etc. as in stereotypical jajmãni duties in Indian multi-caste villages. The village households actually maintain jajmãni ties with tailors and blacksmiths in another village over an hours’ walk away. In short, Prindle was discussing haliyã, not jajmãni. He needed to discuss the interactions between hali and jajmãni. Contrary to degradation theories, Prindle states that jajmãni practices endure which contradicts the thesis of Blustain's review article. The jajmãni relationship between Brãhman and tailor or blacksmith in Prindle’s study is extremely durable if village opinion is any gauge: Those households (three Brãhman, four Bhujel) that have terminated their jajmãni ties try to economize by using the services of these specialists only when absolutely necessary. ...However, the fact that these households do not pay bãli is well known in Tinglatar [Prindle’s research site] and looked upon by others in very critical terms. The offenders are constantly reminded of their degraded position and, in general, granted very little respect.(ibid:292) Prindle concludes that even under severe agricultural failure, which occurred during his study period, jajmãni remained strong and enduring. The most thorough treatment of jajmãni relations in Blustain’s review is that of Lionel Caplan’s study of administrative relations in the capital of Dailekh (located next to Jãjarkoë District). Surprisingly Blustain chose Lionel Caplan's work focusing on administrative changes 67 in the capital when Patricia Caplan, working with her then-husband, studied rural farming outside the District Capital. Her book, Priests and Cobblers (1972) is overtly about caste productive relations of jajmãni. Patricia also published her monograph three years before Lionel‘s so Blustain had opportunity to use it. Like examples of writers ignoring Charlotte Wiser’s writing in favor of Ben Wiser’s, Blustain might have felt women's writing cannot be as empirical as a man’s. Lionel Caplan’s results, although he focuses on administration rather than agriculture, still find that low caste artisans’ jajmãni relationships benefit from capital ties in the District Center rather than degrade. In talking with a Damãi tailor in the Dailekh bazaar: ‘Many of us want to drop our clients, but (men like) my father’ with whom he shares a joint household - ‘thinks clients mean security and refuses to give them up. So he and my mother and wife do the work for clients, and I do the piece-work’. Every practicing Tailor in the bazaar has an Indian-made machine, invariably purchased in the terãi . Women work alongside the men, but sew only by hand. (1975:83) From L. Caplan’s discussions it appears that jajmãni is changing, not simply disappearing. I found similar results in Jãjarkoë to L. and P. Caplan’s reports. Jãjarkoë and Dailekh Districts are contiguous and their District Capitals have similar growth patterns. I might also point out that informants are usually casual about remarking on the work of female tailors. Yet somewhere between the informant’s descriptions of the work that female tailors do, and the researchers more analytical generalizations, women’s work is often erased from the published account. Patricia Caplan (1972:87), though her work on jajmãni was not reviewed by Beidleman, was working in rural circumstances which provide a clear statement of the continuing and thriving nature of jajmãni: Nor have those untouchables in Duari who still practice their caste-specific occupations within a jajmãni framework, suffered as a result of economic development. Their services are still very 68 much in demand, since virtually no manufactured goods such as tools or clothes are imported into the bazaar (they would have to be brought from India and would be very expensive). Also, Veronique Bouillier wrote a thorough article entitled “Economic relationships between occupational castes and high castes in central Nepal” (1977) which deals more directly with Blustain’s subject than any of his review choices. V. Bouillier describes the employer craftsman relationship which she calls bãli-Kãmi or bãli-Damãi. This is one of the only treatments on exactly what implements ironsmiths make and she gives information of payments for services as well. Her piece is only descriptive, with no connotations of degradation. Most of the literature on jajmãni highlights the changing if not degradational aspects of jajmãni. J. Elder’s conclusion sums up his and his colleagues views: In his pioneering work in 1936 Wiser [William, not Charlotte] stated: ‘The Hindu Jajmãni System cannot continue as it now exists.’ In 1959 Beidelman stated that massive economic and political changes had occurred in India ‘in a combination and on a scale and intensity sufficient to cause grave conflict within such a system, a conflict which will ultimately make the jajmaani system obsolete.’...This paper...has suggested specific patterns one can look for in the decrease of core jajmaani relationships. (1970:12627). Elder could have interpreted the literature on jajmãni as enduring in that from 1930, to 1936, to 1959, to 1970, until the present, researchers continued to find viable jajmãni relations. In 1990, in Jãjarkoë 117 of 120 household interviews in the villages up to four hours' walk away from the District Capital continue to use patron-client relations. The tie between patrons and service specialists endures because it is integrated with many related labor practices and social hierarchies. Jajmãni is part of bonded labor, indigenous loans, simple labor intensive agricultural technology, and the caste system of social hierarchy. Jajmãni and variations such as khalo have not simply disappeared, at least in Jãjarkoë District, because jajmãni constitutes part of a social organization of indigenous labor. 69 Payments and Exchange in Jajmãni Relations Researchers wish to systematize information in a Western empirical pattern incommensurate with fine gradations of payment in jajmãni. Payments often recognize services such as playing music for weddings, giving ëika ritual marks, washing feet, serving as day laborer during the patron’s celebrations, and even doing housekeeping. Artisans rarely measure their incomes on a ‘yearly’ basis since recompense comes in the form of favors, political alliances, voting persuasions, and a pound of grain ‘here and there’ in addition to semi-annual collections of grain following harvest. In Jãjarkoë, services are usually remunerated according to the judged needs of the artisan’s family. Yet there remains an strong ethic of equal exchange even under socially asymmetrical circumstances. As the Jãjarkoëi tailor’s saying goes, “Just as you serve the food, so we will sew the clothes.” Making relationships commensurate depends on a range of bartered decisions, grain,, goods and other forms of capital. Reports of payment in the literature for jajmãni partners is highly variable. Most early jajmãni literature lacks empirical information concerning payments for services. E. Harper complains that “Nowhere in the literature is there an analysis of precisely how payments are determined.” (1959:164) Fixed wages are based on an exchange form (grain, land) that is constant rather than fluctuating with the market, like money. Harper hypothesizes that grain or fixed payments in land are more valued than money since low castes meet most of their subsistence needs regardless of fluctuations in the economy. While this may be so, in Jãjarkoë, payments to artisans fluctuate with harvest yields. In good years, artisans can beg for more off the threshing floor (khal). No literature directly addresses this, however. Since the 1960’s several researchers have provided information on jajmãni payments (in Jãjarkoë called khal, or sida for Brãhmans) but the information about jajmãni payments is difficult to synthesize. Across South Asia there are different units of measurement and types of payment such as land, grain, favors, or religious duties which may all be part of jajmãni 70 payments. In addition, writers tend to present their data sometimes statistically, sometimes anecdotally and sometimes they do not give enough information for comparison. H. Blustain details grain payments to 21 Damãi and Kãmi caste families in north central Nepal. One piece of data shows the category ‘Damãi’ (15 households) as receiving 90 muris of unspecified type of grain as income from bãli (jajmãni ) (1984:14). This obviously cannot be used for comparative purposes. We don’t know if each household got 90 muris, or if 90 muris is the total amount give to all 15 households. We also don’t know what type of grain was given or when since stereotypically artisans receive amounts of grain after each harvest of rice, wheat, barley, etc. J. Benson (1976; near Hyderabad) gives detailed information on ‘Payments to Service Castes’. She cites 5 low castes comprising a total of 10 households and gives detailed jajmãni income data on land and grain. Gould (1964; eastern Uttar Pradesh) gives quantified data on payments by caste category though his goal is to create an ‘economic score’ of ‘orthodox’ economic ties with other jajmãni specialists. Most researchers did not adopt Gould’s methodology which makes comparison difficult. M. Orans’ article is a hypothetical economic exercise using unspecified data “derived from village studies in India, Pakistan, and Ceylon.” (1968:875). D. Miller studied central Indian asami relations, like jajmãni, in an extended household of potters and their relations with the village patrons. He questioned whether monetization undermines traditional patronage because traditional exchange reinforces the ‘secondary articulation of formal exchange with other aspects of village social organization.” Asami relations, then, are part of deeper social ties/obligations among community members. As related obligations, Miller cites potters serving meals at social functions, arranging prayers, anointing with the ëilak mark, drawing water for festivals or long term contracts, playing music (with musician castes), presenting auspicious vessels to guests, playing ritual roles for the goddess Shitala Mata or Ganesh (1986: 540-41). 71 Miller points out that previous (degradationist) articles on jajmãni, (he cites Gough 1960; Kolenda 1978; and Lewis and Barnouw 1967), are based on the argument that the jajmãni system is undermined by the spread of the cash economy. Each article relies on dichotomous approaches, “opposing, for example, capitalist against pre capitalist and substantivist against formalist economic forms...”(1986:545). This approach measures jajmãni relations through units of analysis (pound, mana, quintal) which obfuscate meaningful social relations in jajmãni. Such attempts will not succeed in understanding the “secondary articulations” or complete set of obligations between patrons and artisans. Most notably, patronage seldom exists without multiple ties of other named practices, such as bonded labor, which bind laborer to patron. A Review of Bonded Labor Occasionally writers conflate bonded labor with jajmãni and its variations. While related, the practices are distinct and are best understood as separate named practices before analyzing their relationship. In the reviews below Campbell (1978) obscures the relationships of bonded labor and patronage. From discussion on patronage, we observed that Prindle (1977) also conflated the two labor practices. Other writers, notably, Breman (1974), Bishop (1990), Ishii (1982), and INSEC (1992) do not conflate bonded labor and patronage (jajmãni). These references give informed discussions of bonded labor and its ties to the greater economy. Bonded labor in Jãjarkoë is essentially different from jajmãni or khalo in several respects. First, the bonded laborer (haliyã) may come from any caste, including a high caste; there is no caste ascribed duty. Second, the work of haliyã is overwhelmingly agricultural; "hali" literally refers to hal: 'plow' which may be an etymological relationship to Indo-European *har (plow). Third, people become bonded laborers by taking indigenous loans and not ix repaying them. This is not the case in jajmãni relationships. Says B.K. Thãru of bonded labor: "Rs. 600 taken to buy a buffalo went up to Rs. 6,000 because of the interest of 30%. Further, I 72 have to pay 60% interest for the loan of Rs. 5,000 taken by my forefathers." (INSEC 1992:94) This is a testimony of a bonded laborer from a district south of Jãjarkoë. In the southern terãi , bonded labor is common. In these regions there are larger landholdings and more cash cropping. While bonded laborers (haliyã) are uncommon in Jãjarkoë, they nevertheless contribute to overall indigenous labor relations. Descriptions of Bonded labor One of the most extensive writings on the subject of bonded labor outside Nepal is J. Breman's work, Patronage and Exploitation (1974). In it Breman states that the relationship of Bãhun land owners and low caste landless laborers contains elements of an historic social relationship known as the hali system (halipratha), even though legally it was abolished decades ago. Breman feels that in order to understand changes in the present relationships between landowners and landless laborers, we must know the essential importance of past social relations. Breman discusses essential aspects of the relationship between landowner, "dhaniãmo" (Nepãli: jaggã dhani, sauji, riti , or malikdãr are all nuanced connotations for “landowner”) and the haliyã. Hali relationships are long standing, often two or more generations' duration. Hali laborers generally have a more secure subsistence position than a free laborer since the dhaniãmo provides for the haliyã family's basic subsistence, like the patron-client relation found in jajmãni relations. The dhaniãmo - hali relation begins with the dhaniãmo's decision to lend a significant amount of money to the hali, an amount which both parties can stereotypically never be repaid. The debt accrues, with interest, and is passed from generation to generation of sons and sometimes daughters. Indeed, the hali's strategy is to place himself even further into debt by annual requests for enough grain or money to meet subsistence levels. 73 Through increased bondage, the hali never has to worry about being removed from the owner's property; the hali only has obligations to be available whenever the owner needs labor. While excellent for comparative purposes, Breman's work takes place in southern Gujarat which contains historical and geographic conditions different from Jãjarkoë. The Gujarat area is more commoditized, has more roads and bazaars, has much larger landholdings per owner, and is governed by Indian law and political problems. There was a Gandhian movement in the 1930’s to abolish bonded labor which never occurred in Nepal, for example. J. Breman (1974) contributed to the discussion of whether jajmãni is a total system by pointing out the falsely imposed division between jajmãni and other labor practices, especially hali. In many regions the agricultural laborer traditionally fulfilled some functions of a ritual nature in the house of the landlord (1974:14). In these castes there was unquestionably a jajmãni relationship as well as other ties to bind worker to patron. But overall, haliyã were often not tied to their overlords through complementary jajmãni relations. In Nepal the issue of bonded labor has been commented upon. Patricia Caplan (1972), J. Gabrielle Campbell (1978), Hiroshi Ishii (1982), Augusta Molnar (1980), M. C. Regmi (1978a; 1978b), a report by INSEC (1992), and B. Bishop (1990:193-94) mention or analyze bonded and free labor conditions. These writings from Nepal provide a suitable framework for a comparison of the hali system with bonded and coerced labor in Jãjarkoë. P. Caplan, working in Dailekh District bordering Jãjarkoë, describes a system of haliriti, or 'ploughman - master' similar to hali discussed by Breman. Landowners, usually Brãhman since they are tabooed from ploughwork, lend money to ploughmen who agree to work until the debt is repaid. In return, the hali works for the riti whenever called upon and receives about 3 muri of grain, or half of his yearly subsistence requirements. She also mentions 'legends of karia', people that were likely to be called upon by high castes in times of need and who were rewarded in grain (1972:33). Interestingly, this may be the only English reference to the practice of baure (to call casual laborers) which is common in Jãjarkoë. Yet the 74 word karia is not used in Jãjarkoë and could just as well refer to slaves (Nep: kamãro , “slave”) or some other category of worker. Overall, Caplan's discussion, though brief, correctly elucidated the differences between the named labor forms of hali and jajmãni. It is evident from Caplan's description that similar work relationships existed in Dailekh in 1972 to those I found in Jãjarkoë in 1990. The karia relationship, though scantily described, sounds familiar to baure casual labor and hali. The loan which bonds hali to riti in Dailekh certainly occurs in Jãjarkoë as well. As my data show in Chapter Five, lending between high and low castes is still common. Laborers tend to take Kabul, indentured service loans while landlords tend to give such loans. Even in 1990, low castes tend to indenture themselves through loans. J. Campbell mentions the laagi-laagitya variation of jajmãni in Jumlã, just north of Jãjarkoë District. Campbell conflates jajmãni and hali since many artisan castes worked as plowmen and agricultural laborers: “...some laagitya who work as plowers and conduct almost all the agricultural work for wealthy Brãhmans or Thakuris are placed in a special status whereby they receive considerably more grain and clothes and are sometimes given their own plots of land to grow their own crops." [1978: 75] He calls these more privileged hali “badahali ” and cites B.K. Shrestha (2028 [1971]) as doing the same. Hali in Jãjarkoë work on a more informal basis and they do not normally work as artisans and plowmen at the same time though members of one extended family will contain both hali and active artisans. There may be some leather working castes in northern Jãjarkoë who practice badahali though I did not interview any such workers. Throughout the discussion, Campbell appears to poorly distinguish hali relationships from patron - artisanship. Mary Cameron (personal communication) also works in far western Nepal, in Bajhang District where she describes a form of jajmãni known as riti bhagya. Again, showing the tendency to combine hali with jajmãni she cites cases where low castes, which she calls by the Hindi word "dom", are given “temporary sharecrop” (adhiyå) or “plough” (hali) by the ruling 75 caste (in personal conversation). Since Bajhang, like Jãjarkoë, retained its Rãjã under Nepal’s Rãjã into the twentieth century, haliyã was a form of land tenancy where low castes use the land and its harvest in exchange for ploughing the King’s fields. In Jãjarkoë riti bhagya was not practiced but instead adhiyå was the dominant form of sharecropping. One of the only pieces of published information on hali payments is given in B. Bishop’s writing. He mentions hali as of "special importance to the tagadãri [thread bearing twice born high castes], especially the Bãhuns, because they "eschew earthly agricultural work in general and plowing in particular". Plowmen receive about 100 - 120 mana from their sauji (patrons/landowners/ jaggãdhani / riti). In addition many hali are given .5-1.5 mãëo muri (64191m2) of land (1990:193-94). Like P. Caplan, Bishop is careful to distinguish between hali and patron - artisan relations. Recently the Informal Sector Service Centre (INSEC 1992) reveals that workers in kamãiya (bonded labor) in southwest Nepal (Bardia, Kanchanpur, and Kailali Districts) work excessively, borrow cash and/or in-kind loans (saùki), and involve their other family members in indebtedness. Women in bonded labor situations in addition are often forced into sexual service for their masters. The study documented loan notes which masters sell to other masters. The study by INSEC found this form of bonded labor is popular in the terãi lowlands. They opined that kamãiya and bonded labor in general was a remnant of the slavery system abolished initially in 1924. Unlike Breman's opinion that bondage ensured subsistence and a margin of safety, INSEC found living conditions to be inhumane. Although bonded labor is infrequent in Jãjarkoë, I witnessed below subsistence conditions for bonded laborers. Bonded laborers frequently had endemic parasites, malnutrition, mental illness, and little or no personal possessions. Rather than side with Breman's conclusions, I found the reports by INSEC to be more accurate. INSEC, being a Nepãli organization, was not the slightest confused about distinctions between jajmãni and bonded labor. Regarding women as bonded laborers or servants, I did document one case of severe abuse leading to death of the servant. She had been 76 sexually abused which was what lead to the circumstances of her death. Servants, nominally family members, are employed to serve for life and whether they are free to depart is questionable. L. Caplan (1980:168) described such persons as “...chattels owned by masters who could be bought and sold.” Masters had the power of life/death over their servants. If master kills servant, the case can be tried as murder and is punishable under law. But the master‘s political and economic persuasion is great; masters generally avoid extreme penalties. Hiroshi Ishii described intricacies of agricultural labor recruitment in Nepal, including the relationship between slavery, bonded and free labor (1982). He noted that when "a landlord hires a specific person constantly as a jãladar (free laborer) mainly for ploughing and pays him daily, the laborer is called a 'nimek-hali' " (1982:59). In this case the hali need not be bound by debt although it is probable. For example, Ishii described how the hali "could be sold to other people if he could not repay his debt or failed to satisfy his master by his work. In the case of a hali dying before the repayment of the debt leaving his offspring, the master could sell the children, who were called "slaves": kamãro (kamãri in feminine declension)" (1982:59-60). Writers often debated whether bonded laborers were better off than free laborers, servants or slaves. The relative qualities of life of each of these groups seems to have been compared often. Yet the important issue of inequality between those in service to others and those obtaining services is mentioned by none except the writers of the INSEC report. When one debates whether slaves or bonded laborers are better off, the real issue - that neither has any real human rights - is obscured. Bonded labor and patronage represent two distinct yet overlapping types of labor management. Householders will use one rather than the other as they weigh their agricultural and economic situations. Householders use patronage (jajmãni, khalo) when they live near artisans and priests, have little access to commodities, use little money for exchange, and own enough land to give up a portion of the harvest in exchange for services. Householders obtain bonded labor when they need extra labor constantly, can afford to maintain another extra- 77 household member, have extra grain and money for lending, and wish to divert their own time away from working in agriculture. Both types of bosses (sauji) always come from the high caste elite strata of Nepalese society. In the next section on the labor forms parimã and sahayog, we see that householders can enlarge their network of labor options. Parimã and sahayog are used mainly under egalitarian circumstances between labor partners. Reciprocal Labor and Gifts of Labor Reciprocity (parimã) and labor gifting or help (sahayog) present two additional important labor options for householders. The definitional boundaries of parimã and sahayog are fairly loose, enabling flexibility of use. Most researchers have narrowly focused on only one or two labor practices, such as jajmãni. They miss seeing the role of parimã or sahayog within the greater network of labor management options. For this reason, very little has been written about these informal labor practices. Secondly, previous writers on the subject of parimã have not addressed the nature of power in the exchange relations. From my work on parimã it appears that reciprocal labor is egalitarian when partners have similar volumes of composite capital, i.e., they display similar amounts of political, economic, cultural, and symbolic resources. When households have unequal amounts of capital, the household with more land, political power, or influence may exert pressure on the other household to donate extra labor time. I argue that future research needs to explore whether this holds true in Nepal and South Asia in general. Broadly, reciprocal labor in Jãjarkoë is an agreement between two or more households to pool their resources, including irrigation, bullocks, and labor, for agricultural work during peak labor periods. One of the interesting things about reciprocal labor is its fluid nature; it is generalized and adaptable to local concerns. H. Ishii wrote that "Parimã is a form of one to one labour exchange" (1982:48) while other researchers state or suggest that reciprocal labor is a group effort, a form of cooperation, or a means of combining forces during peak labor periods. 78 B. Bishop states that parimã is a strategy of combining "forces in a system of reciprocal or exchange labor" and notes that careful scheduling has to be done in order to assure that the supply of the number of women (literally “planters” or roparni in Jãjarkoë) equals the amount of work needed (1990:192). L. Caplan too, writes, "At peak seasons, moreover, to cope better with these [agricultural] duties several households combine their labour to work in large teams on a direct exchange basis (here called hade-parimã)." (1975: 119). As both J. Hitchcock and A. Molnar mention, the Magar ethnic group also uses reciprocal labor. Hitchcock begins a chapter in his monograph on Magar life with the opening paragraph: "The most common kind of work group is formed on the basis of what is called porimã or orimã porimã..." (1966:85). Hitchcock bases his reference on fieldwork done in 1955-56 and represents one of the earliest accounts by a western researcher. x Semantic boundaries constituting reciprocal labor are open to interpretation. One defining characteristic in Jãjarkoë is that parimã and baure stretch to the boundaries of their definitional space among other forms of labor such as “free labor” and “bonded labor”. In Jãjarkoë I have heard parimã defined and practiced in a number of elastic variations depending on the needs of the practitioner. At various times reciprocal labor is a relationship of one to one, household to household, or village work gang. Similarly, reciprocal labor varies geographically and historically so that Hitchcock's, Caplan's, Bishop's and my own interpretations represent thematic variations which a universal definition would do injustice. As C. Humphery and S. Hugh-Jones write of barter, “Attempts to produce a universal definition or model of barter usually involve stripping it from its social context and result in imaginary abstractions that have little or no correspondence to reality.” (1992:1). Likewise, one universal definition of parimã, jajmãni, or any of the indigenous labor practice would ultimately fail to embody all the variations across Nepal. Most of the time parimã includes a principle of egalitarian reciprocity. Partners are supposed to exchange equal labor days whenever possible. No authors have presented precise 79 data on labor days given - received. Messerschmidt (1981) proves anecdotal evidence on labor given -received in a Gurung ethnic community. I believe that while parimã has much more egalitarian tenets than patronage, bonded labor, and even wage and casual labor, it still unites households with unequal compositions of capital who sometimes try to gain greater leverage even in egalitarian labor exchanges. The other egalitarian, informal type of work is sahayog, meaning "help" or "donation". H. Ishii is the only writer who actually describes the practice and he calls it gwahar or alternatively guhar. “Madat,” simply meaning “help” is another commonly used term. Ishii states: Gwahar is only practiced in special cases. If it happens that there is no able person in the household in a busy season because of illness, accident or other reasons, neighbors or close kin may come to help. But as one can hire agricultural labourers by paying in cash or kind in ordinary cases, this kind of help is limited to the work of a short period or to the financially deprived cases. (1982:49-50). He also mentions that although no remuneration is expected, a donation of one mana of grain is acceptable. Ishii’s description corresponds to most of my observed circumstances in Jãjarkoë. An even broader definition relates to the person who gives help as a “friend”. Thus the sahãyak or madati is simply a friend who helps one out in times of need (T. Singh B. S. 1981:620) A Note on Wage Labor and Rural Households Wage labor and capitalist relations of production are certainly related to indigenous labor practices though they are not the focus of my dissertation. I will mention a few resources which focus on wage labor relations in rural Nepal. In these rural settings indigenous labor clearly interacts with capitalist wage labor practices. 80 Meena Acharya (1987) did her Ph.D. Thesis on rural labor markets in Nepal and provides quantitative information on the status of workers and owners. She does not address the role of indigenous labor in capitalist situations however. Bishnu Bhandari (1985) focuses on land ownership with emphasis on factors involving quality of life related to landed/landlessness. Bhandari discusses migrancy, portering, and other wage labor. He refers to unskilled agricultural labor (hali? jãladãri? no Nepali term given) but does not discuss this practice. The research team of P. Blaikie, J. Cameron, and D. Seddon have studied social classes and labor relations from several angles, including effects of roadways and environmental degradation (Blaikie, Cameron, and Seddon 1977; 1980), and of alienation of means of production and of access to food (Seddon, Blaikie, and Cameron 1979; 1987). Their work mentions jajmãni and artisanal - landowner relationships but does not explore the relationship of capitalist wage labor to indigenous labor management. Integrated Development Studies (1985; 1986) informs development policy makers about the living conditions of wage workers and agricultural sharecroppers. No mention is made of bonded laborers though one might guess that many of their reports target this group. Feldman and Fornier’s article, “Social Relations and Agricultural Production in Nepal’s terãi ” (1976) was seminal in providing my first insights concerning Nepal’s agrarian class structure. They contributed excellent information about the role of migrants in cash cropping in the terãi , but they do not mention bonded labor or other indigenous labor practices. Several good migration studies (S. Gurung 1978; Manzardo, Dahal, and Rai 1977; N. Shrestha 1990) have all made contributions to understanding unskilled laborers who journey off their farms or away from local precarious economic situations. Thus, a fair beginning of literature exists in Nepal concerning wage labor relations and capitalist relations of production in rural settings. Yet these authors have not addressed the issues of indigenous labor management and patronage as an integral part of Nepal’s economic system. 81 Conclusions In reviewing the literature on indigenous labor, I have found that researchers failed to recognize a clear distinction between labor practices. Most importantly, skilled artisanship (khalo) and unskilled agricultural labor (baure, hali) are discussed as part of a "jajmãni system" with little reference to local variations, payment schedules, or extra obligations. Generally unskilled agricultural labor has been ignored and divorced from studies of patronage (jajmãni). Indeed, there is almost another genre of books about bonded labor in India. Another problem of jajmãni reporting appears to be that researchers believed in the degradation of jajmãni yet did not look carefully at empirical economic data. Their research sites often were located in urbanizing villages and along highways (Epstein 1967, Gough 1960, Blustain 1984). Their theories tended to be dualistic, pitting capitalism against “pre-capitalism” and modern against traditional economies. Such false dichotomies merely obfuscate real relations of production. Finally, researchers tended to forget that exchange relations take place within a dual social hierarchy of caste and class. Jajmãni and other labor management practices are imbued with inequality, just as wage labor is, though under a set of historically different circumstances. Even reciprocal labor and gifts of labor need to be scrutinized as inherently unequal labor exchange practices rather than balanced or delayed reciprocity. By reading research specifically concerning Nepal, one may get little understanding of indigenous labor relationships. Of the indigenous labor practices which occur in Jãjarkoë District, largely undocumented practices include casual labor (baure), gifts of labor (sahayog), and reciprocal labor (parimã). The most information on indigenous labor practices is found in B. Bishop 1990; L. Caplan 1970; 1975; P. Caplan 1972; INSEC 1992; H. Ishii 1982; D. Messerschmidt 1981; Blustain 1984; and P. Prindle 1977. There appears to be less reporting by Nepalese researchers on indigenous labor practices. Om Gurung 1987 and D.B. Bista 1972 are two exceptions. O. Gurung wrote about rodighar (dormitories of youth who also do casual and 82 festive labor). K.B. Bista commented on kumãune , another variation of jajmãni. xi Occasionally the exploitation of a caste or ethnic group is outlined which touches on issues of coerced labor, as in Singh 2048 B.S. (1991 A.D.). Research on indigenous labor management needs to be done in order to distinguish between labor forms and comprehend non-capitalist economic logics. Most agricultural researchers are just realizing that local management of resources and labor exist. They know little about them in their social, political, and economic contexts. Urban educated Nepali professionals generally know little about managing agricultural production using indigenous methods. One of the challenges of the next decade, as wage labor and evolving forms of capitalism become more commonplace in places like Jãjarkoë, will be to mesh Western knowledge of agricultural productive relations with indigenous strategies. No index entries found. N otes to Chapter Two iSince M.C. Regmi has written exhaustively on the subject of land tenure and tenancy, I review land tenure-related literature only when it interacts with indigenous labor practices. Interested readers should review Bhandari 1985; Caplan 1970; IDS 1985; 1986; Manzardo 1977; Theisenhusen 1988; M. C. Regmi 1963; 1971; 1969 - 1986; and Zaman 1973 for the history and politics of land tenure in Nepal. ii The term khalo is commonly used in Jajarkot. In other parts of Nepal the following terms are also used: bistã, bãli , kumãune. Bista means, literally "client" and refers to the household which commissions artisanal work. Bãli refers to the portion of the harvest. V. Boullier (1977) calls khalo "bãli -damãi" when dealing with a tailor and his/her payments. The reference "kumaune" literally mean "to earn" and refers to the artisan earning a portion of the harvest from the agriculturalist. iii iv Hanseri, a Hindi word, was used occasionally by people indicating their more elite knowledge of Hindi. The Nepali word, begãr, is one word for labor conscripted by the State. "Unskilled labor" is a misnomer. It takes an incredible amount of knowledge about environmental conditions, management of labor resources, and plant and animal esoteria to successfully be an agriculturalist or livestock herder. In Jãjarkoë, agricultural "casual labor" is not deskilled in any way. In wage labor jobs such as portering, road construction, etc. skill levels do vary. 83 v Fuller (1989), on nineteenth century references to jajmãni, states that K. Marx used information from East Indian Trading Company records to formulate ideas about Indian political economy, including reference to jajmãni. Max Weber knew about the jajmani practices as well. Thus there was some previous information available. vi Leach viewed artisans as commanding economic power and jajamãn patrons as competing for their favor! Economic roles are allocated by right to [low castes]...members of the high-status ‘dominant caste’, to whom the low-status groups are bound, generally form a numerical majority and must compete among themselves for the services of individual members of the lower ‘castes’. (1960:6)...For me, caste as distinct from either social class or caste grade manifests itself in the external relations between caste groupings. These relations stem from the fact that every caste, not merely the upper élite, has its special ‘privileges’. (1960:7) E. Leach may be correct that anecdotal cases exist of low castes commanding a sort of supply and demand control over their services, such as in Jajarkot bazaar when a handful of tailors are busy most of the time with their bistãs‘ (Nep.: patrons’) work. In the vast majority of cases low caste artisans have little leverage in the relationship since they have little capital or power, readymade goods are common, and patrons can sever the relationship rather easily. vii Two works have recently come to my attention concerning the nineteenth century forms of jajmãni. See Commander 1983 and Mayer 1993. Also, Burton Stein’s work, Peasant State and Society in Medieval South India indirectly explores early jajmãni and other caste informed relations. He refers to castes, some known as rathakarar (1980:197-98) who are threadwearing artisans of a “left caste” (valangai: Tamil). However, comparisons with Nepal either past or present are sketchy. Stein himself notes that ‘The traditionally known varnã system - Brahman, Kshatriya, Vaisa, Sudra, is not complete here [in south India]. No Kshatriya castes exist and Brahmans thus emerged as dominant secular powers.’ (1980:71). viii Bhujel, according to Prindle, are an ethnic group employed as bonded laborers (hali plowmen) and probably female agricultural fieldhands though Prindle doesn't mention what Bhujel women actually do. ix Besides haliyã , bonded laborers have been called kamãiyã (<kãm, "work") (INSEC 1992) in Nepal. Kamãiyã is a cognate of kamãra or kamãri, meaning slave. x Hitchcock reported that "porima" means to "lend an arm" which contradicts the meaning given to me, "after me" (from pachi mã[>pari mã). Personally, I think that when villagers are asked for a translation, sometimes they make educated guesses. Perhaps both glosses have historical significance as meanings for porimã and parima. xi I asked Nanda Shrestha, a Nepalese colleague who works in economic and political issues of anthropological interest, if he knew of Nepali writings concerning the indigenous labor relations with which I am concerned. He could recall no such writings. He did describe 84 reading something about sahayog. N. Shrestha said the piece he read, he couldn't remember the source, refered to a group raising money together, sometimes through the initiation of the Nepalese government. This was probably a reference to the government sponsored program in the 1960's called Sãjhã. It was a compulsory savings program (HMG 1962). It used the rhetoric of helping one's fellow citizens and might have used the word "sahayog." Sãjhã, incidently, was a total failure, even by the HMG - Nepal's own admission. 90 xviii There exists an ongoing discussion of whether social classes exist outside a capitalist paradigm (Giddens 1973). I hold that social classes exist wherever one segment of society owns and controls the resources while non-owners are dependent upon owners for production and reproduction. Such a schema can be found in lineage based societies (Dupré and Rey 1978; Coquery-Vidrovitch 1978) which are not capitalist, for example. Thus I argue social class is not limited in history or culture to capitalist relations of production. xix xx Wolpe (1980) used the 1961, Moscow foreign Languages Publishing House edition of Capital in this quotation. xxi 2 There are four or five levels of water management in Jãjarkoë. Each entails several kinds of labor relations but not necessarily one type of labor relation correlates with one type of water management. Reciprocal labor groups may use government sponsored irrigation works as well as sharecroppers of absentee landlords. Koyas are an ethnic group in South India listed on tribal rolls. 2 From migratio, Latin for "to remove, move away," the practice of moving has been common prior to capitalist informed migratory practices. In Nepal capitalist informed migration began with the tea plantations near Darjeeling in the then province of Nepal in the late 1700's/early 1800's which were organized by the British (Dahal, Rai, Manzardo 1977; M. C. Regmi 1979). xxiii I gloss signifiers as any symbol, signal, or sign meant to deliver a message and elicit a specific, though multivocalic, idea. xxiv For critiques of feudal models of production in South Asia see Byres, 1985; Habib, 1985; Mukhia, 1981; 1985; Rudra, 1981; 1988; Stein, 1985; Sharma, 1985. xxv While Merovingian and Carolingian ages of feudalism, from fifth to tenth centuries form the core of Bloch's characterization, he does create a dynamic rather than static representation of feudalism by dealing with unstable conditions of feudal polity continuing through the fourteenth century and later as capitalism becomes dominant. xxvi Mukhia's first instance of difference: "European feudalism developed essentially as changes at the base of society took place; in India ...establishment of feudalism is attributed by ... state action in granting land in lieu of salary or in charity [land grants], and action of the grantees in subjecting the peasantry by means of legal rights assigned to them by the state['forced labor']." (1981:286). Despite land grants and forced labor, Mukhia goes on to state difference in serfdom, land holding size, productivity of agriculture, technologies, private property rights, as some of the reasons Indian agricultural history differs from European feudalism. His argument, dense and particularistic, I find unconvincing. xxvii Bloch's definition, with its emphasis on warrior elites, I find unduly patriarchal. 91 xxviii Since I began researching articulating productive logics, I noticed writers hesitate to boldly state their beliefs about capitalism versus other "undertakings." I would be pleased to read anyone's ideas about a theoretical tyranny of capitalist perspective. Writers continue to pay homage to the "global economy" (capitalism) without researching noncapitalist economic logics and their political persuasions. I hypothesize this has something to do with capitalist fears of "other political systems" such as communism or african systems which were forcibly colonized and made to take up European political-economic governing rules. xxix Bailey cites Godelier 1969:49, "...l'existence combinée communautés primitives où régne la possession du sol et organisés, partiellement encore, sur la base des rapports de parenté, et d'un pouvair d'Etat, qui exprime l'unité réele ou imaginaire des communautés, contrôle l'usage des resources économiques essentielles et s'approprie directement une partie du travail et de la production des communautés qu'il damine." xxx Before 1850 there are only a few inscriptions about landownership. Private holdings with in-kind taxations dominated. There were many types of taxes however which points to finely graded assessments of production, if not landholdings. xxxi I organize water resource use for irrigation in Jãjarkoë by four types or "levels" of management: 1) mñl, springs from mountain tops and sides which are used for drinking and occasionally channeling onto high fields using little manipulation; 2) lower riverlets which are manipulated using water weirs, stone walls, sumps, etc.; 3) farmer-organized and managed irrigation canals which are labor intensive, managed by a cooperative, and where water rights are carefully meted out; and 4) state sponsored irrigation projects which may have canals of over five kilometers in length. These later of course get catagorized according to State and Development criteria, such as whether they also have hydroelectric capabilities, whether they are multipurpose, whether they are locally contracted and "small," etc. xxxii Some of the administrative functionaries during the Khasa Kingdom in the Jãjarkoë region during the 11th - 14th centuries according to S.M. Adhikary, 1988: Mandalika (governors), Rauttarãjã (ministers), Sarvagãminivãhini (army), many types of tax collectors, Karkyã (Secretary), Danïã (fines collected from defeated territories and the collectors themselves), mahãmanïalesvãrã (Prime Minister), Joisõ (learned Brãhmans),, Parambhattarãjã, Maharãjãdhirãjã (Sovereign King), Adhirãjã (Crown Prince), Mahamanïalesvãrã (Provincial Administrator). xxxiii For example, witness Godelier's view of how historians have inscribed reality: "On the one hand, it [history] was long oriented exclusively toward Western realities,... On the other hand, because many aspects of popular or local life hardly appeared in the written documents that historians studied, they had little choice but to view Western reality through the testimony of those who, in the West as elsewhere, have always used and controlled the practice of writing, that is, the cultured, dominant classes and the various state-controlled administrations (1979:75). 81 4 THE HISTORICAL CONTEXT OF INDIGENOUS LABOR RELATIONS IN THE JAJARKOT REGION "THE Kirtistambha states that taxes were exempted to the Brahmanas, Bhiksus (monks), Dharmabhanakas (preachers), and Sutradharakas (artisans)...they received the tax-exempt lands from the king. (Adhikary 1988:52) The purpose of Chapter Four is threefold. First, I emphasize that the roots of current labor relations can be traced back to the first inscriptions in the region. Material evidence is scant however, except for vamsavali, elite histories of family lineages and a few stone and copper monuments. A central question, but one I ultimately cannot answer without more historical, epigraphic, and archaeological evidence, is 'What are the movements of history which created present indigenous labor relations?' Until an historian well versed in Sinjali, Tibetan, and medieval legal documents whose vocation is archaeology and avocation art history and epigraphy turns up, I can merely provide pieces to the problem. One notable inscription in the region, the Kirtistambha or Dullu Pillar erected in 1357 A.D. (1279 Shakya), proclaimed that the king would provide taxexempt land (birta) to his artisans and priests. With the engraving of one duty of the most elite patron in the Kingdom, the written history of Jajarkot began. A second point in this Chapter is that elite renditions of history cannot speak for the historical happenings of commoners. The first part of this chapter reconstructs some of the early history of Jajarkot using historical information from royal genealogies, (vamsavali), folklore, and archaeological artifacts. In the latter part of this Chapter I present information from interviews with both workers and petty managers of labor projects from the early part of this century. Recent nineteenth and twentieth 82 century history is the focus of the second half of the chapter. I compiled information on recent history through oral histories, interviews with district government offices, and summaries of land dispute court cases. I concentrated on memories of residents in Jajarkot rather than using Nepalese government archives since the jargon and legal writing styles are complex. As an anthropologist I feel most comfortable working with living memories of Jajarkotis. Perhaps an historian, one fluent in Nepali, will take up to task of interpreting land, legal, and tax records, etci. The history presented here stresses recorded events and memories of elite labor relations. The copper plate inscriptions, for example, recount noble lineages, land grants, and rules of taxation. No mention is made of specific indigenous labor relations such as jajmani, khalo, adhiyå, haliya, parima , or sahayog in written records because these are not taxed and they have few formal social rules. Instead, people inscribed information about taxes, land tenures, laws, and land grants. These pieces of information, both written and in oral histories, tell of what is expected of royalty and commoners. In this chapter I present primarily social rules for the roles of village functionaries, land tenures, tax collectors, types of obligatory labor and taxes. One assumption of this Chapter is that the indigenous labor relations of bonded labor (haliya), sharecropping (adhiyå), reciprocal labor (parima), patron-artisanship (khalo), patron-priest (jajmani), lending (rin-din ), and labor gifting (sahayog) are intrinsically related to juridical rules of land tenure and taxation. A final point I wish to make but which this chapter cannot specifically address, is that today's indigenous labor practices in Jajarkot may have roots dating to a medieval Khasa reign, yet labor has certainly changed its character in the twentieth century. The political structure in Nepal shifted from kingdoms to the partyless Panchayat system to democracy. Contingent with these shifts have been changes in land tenure and labor laws. We should assume that previous centuries may well have 83 experienced shifts in political economic structure as well, even if there is scant documented evidence. In short, I wish to paint an image of local labor relations as tied to a historical reality yet also to emphasize the opportunities of each generation to create historically particular sets of labor relations. Early History The history of Jajarkot mingles with the great early kingdoms of western Tibet, Ladakh, northern India, and central Nepal. The history of the people who comprised those kingdoms - the low castes, agriculturalists, pastoralists, traders, and local nobility remains largely unwritten, and therefore archaeological research is necessary to reconstruct important economic and social aspects of western Nepalese history. Jajarkot's sparse historical evidence comes from written documents (Bhattarai 1974; Naraharinath B. S. 2012; His Majesty's Government/Nepal B. S. 2018), stone inscriptions [silapattra] (S. Adhikary 1988; Subedi 1979, 1984), art motifs (P. R. Sharma 1972), and scholarly interpretations of these (Baiddha B. S. 2034; Bajracharya B. S. 2028; Tucci 1956). In order to characterize Jajarkot social relations historically, it is useful to outline major historical conditions in the region. Table 4.1 is an outline of historical events in the Jajarkot region. 84 Table 4.1: Material Conditions in Historical Perspective in Jajarkot Region KTM = Kathmandu; Jaj = Jajarkot Date 1950-1990 AD Historical Events Jajarkot King moves to Kathmandu. Socioeconomic Conditions *Central gov't in KTM. Jaj kingdom effectively ended. Neighboring Regi Tibetan Autonomou China annexed by Effective rule under the state of Nepal and the Panchayat system of governance * Taxes to KTM (Nepal) Return of Shaha D Kathmandu Valle AD) Government bureaucracy begins to expand; public schools built * Property converts to privately held & taxable; all other forms abolished Indian Independe * Incipient wage labor * Caste system strong *1/2 or less money system and 1/2 or more barter sys. *KTM King is deified as God Vishnu; Jaj king is not * Work relations based on 2 caste strata (hi and lo) * compulsory labor can be paid in cash; Labor tax prevalent *Cash tax dominant *Hindu Religion dominant and shamanism strong 1766-1400 A.D. Jajarkot is autonomous kingdom. Broke from the "Khasa Kingdom" of west Nepal and Tibet. Becomes known as one of the "Baisi Raja" or "twenty two autonomous kingdoms. *Separate kingdom from Khasa Mallas of Kathman circa 13th-18th c. *Direct Taxation to Jajarkot king *complex administration *Jajarkot kings deified *Many taxes (produce, labor, head taxes) Rise of Chands (R Himalaya (14th c 85 *Compulsory labor required *Buddhism lessens; Hinduism and shamanism dominate 1400-1100? Jajarkot region has a set of kings under rule of Khasa kings. Much conflict? First monumental works: copper plate inscriptions, stellae, small irrigation, Buddhist shrines *Complex administration; Bahuns and artisans get free land grants *Malla "princes" ruled in Jajarkot; Western Mallas rul probably offshoots of Khasa rulers Kumaon, NW Tibe c. *At least 30 types of taxes Delhi Sultanate ci *Tributary system of taxation Muslim Invasions *Compulsory labor required *land grants to priests, high administrators and artisans. 1100-10 A.D.? "great conquerors" reign; established the first kingdoms in Jajarkot region Immigration of Khasa into western Nepal (ca 0 - 4th c. A.D.) Licchavi Period in (3rd-13th c.) *Buddhist and Hindu religions combined, Buddhist dominant in religious matters, Hindu political organization dominant? Shamanism strong ?Related to the Gupta empire in Tribal Katyuris of India? first oral evidence of kings Himalayas but no evidence of state formations. No info on religious beliefs Pala and Sen Dyna circa 7th c.) Tibetan Military e Classical Gupta P Kirati Period in Ka 7th c B.C. - 3rd c. A 86 87 Much of the early history of the area is reconstructed by aid of vamsavali, royal chronological lists. These give the name of the ruler, an issue date of the monument, and other information for each ruler, such as the names of witnesses to land grants, of patrons of monuments, names of resident officers and their titles,. The genealogies have been found on inscriptions, memorized by pundits, and the better known ones have been written into books (Naraharinath, 1956; Adhikary, 1988). In 1974 an historical archaeological team visited Jajarkot and collected an oral vamsavali from Pandit Shree Moti Lal Sharma in Jagatipur village, a center of traditional Brahmanical knowledge. They published a lineage specifically about Jajarkot rulers, stretching back into prehistory. In it 82 generations of Kings are presented. Other versions feature more generations (At least one scholar, Yogeshwor Karki, recited18 generations between Kings Vijayasingh [circa 1400 A.D.] and Hari Prakash [circa 1890] rather than the 14 which Sharma recites below. King's Name Generation/Year *Dates are unknown in the oral recitation. Brahma Marichi Kasep Surje Ikechu Kuchinn Vikuchi Banana Anarange Prithu Krisanku Susandhi Dhrubasangh 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 Bharatna Asitna Sagar Asamanja Angsu 14 15 16 17 18 Comment "1st King of an area" Had 2 brothers (?line passed through Brother) "Great Conquorer" 88 Dilip Bhagirat 19 20 Kakustha Ragu Prabidha 21 22 23 Samwan Sudharsan Maru Prasusukra Anguwarish Nahush 24 25 26 27 28 29 Yeyati 30 Nabhaga 31 Aj 32 Dasarath 33 Ramchangdraji Chakrajarti 34 Lahari 35 Haridas 36 Tulasidas 37 Bhayenna 38 Kasidas Bisnudas Jayadas Deodas Dewasar Sewasar Irikar Srikar Inbhu Nimbu 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 Kopal Kepari Golas Bharimalla Ubharimalla Araimalla Sindui Rajmalla Dhudhuraj Mairajmalla 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 "Brought Ganges R. from Heaven to Earth" God Basista cursed him into a demon "Maharajadhiraja" King of Kings Had 4 brothers Went away to 'Manjadesh' [Manjusri?] Had 2 brothers; one went to Tibet [Bhot Gaya]; other to Dailekh and killed the Dullu King. Had 4 sons; Conquored Dullu [Enter the Gelas line?] 89 Gotarimalla 58 Gothumalla 59 Jayabhamma (Jayatavarma?) 60 Malaibhamma 61 Jaktisingh Malla Vijayasingh Malla Deusingh Malla Jabhasamma Malla Bikram Raja Punimal Shahi Madhau Shahi Mandhir Shahi Samud Shaha Hari Shaha 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 Hathi Shaha 72 Ban Shahi 73 Gajendra Narayan Shahi 74 / 1760 Indra Narayan Shahi 75 Dip Narayan Shahi 76 /1832 Junga Bahadur Shaha 77 Hari Prakash Narendra Bikram Shaha Upendra Bikram Shaha Soyam Bikram Shaha Prakash Bikram Shaha 78 79 / 1894 80 81 82 Circa 1376 1378-1392 A.D. took Jajarkot region as separate Kingdom from Khasha’s 1398-1404 "Great King" (Pratapi) created "Jajarkot" King of 'Dangrakot' King of Dedara [N. Jajarkot]; Had 2 brothers, the younger was Hathi Killed Hari and his 4 sons. The angry Magar people of Silpachaur in turn killed Hathi and were rewarded with a bullock by the Hari's widow, the Queen of Jajarkot. A son of Hari's by another wife or an adopted son [garthe]. Had 3 sons; made pact with Prithivi Narayan Shaha of Kathmandu son of Indra's sister? Went to Nepal (Ktm valley). Had 3 sons. Powerful. Had 8 sons. Friend of Jung Bah. Rana. Died immediately Had 5 brothers Had 5 brothers Current (ex-)Raja of Jajarkot; Lives in Kathmandu; Including a possible 10 names missing between 1404 and 1735 A.D., the total number of kings would come to 92. Scholar Yogeshwor Karki recounts that "there were 18 generations after Jaya Sinha (Vijayasinha) and finally Hari Bikram Shaha became King" (personal communication). This would be a time frame of approximately 1404 - 90 1735 AD, 331 years. We know for certain that Malaibamma ruled circa 1390 because of copper plate inscriptions found in Jajarkot and elsewhere [Adhikari, 1988:56, App.B38,40]. In the oral vamsavali there were eight Kings after Jaya Sinha, including Hari Shaha. Either these Kings had to rule for 40 years' apiece, or regent's names are missing. In the written history given by Karki-ji there were 18 generations after Jaya Sinha and this seems accurate. It would be about 330 years or 18 years per generation. I tend to believe that the names of several kings must be missing from the written report of the oral vamsaavali since a King normally would entitle one of his sons each generation rather than rule for forty years. In Adhikary's calculations of Khasa kings he also adopts the "20 years per rule" standard. (Here, “Khasa” refers to Indic speaking peoples who migrated into western Nepal from the Indo-Persian geopolitical regions of the west-central Himalayan hills. Khasa people, men especially, may have intermarried with Tibetic speaking indigenous peoples in the area as well.) Given an average 20 year reign per king and the unlikely assumption that the remaining names before Malaibamma's are correct and complete, the line of rulers would reach back 1,820 years to 130 A.D. Also note that the first five names on the list are names of supernatural deities, rather than historical personages. The precise time period is unknown as to when Jajarkot tribes or chiefdoms evolved into an early state formation. Since the first 35 names on the list, from circa 100 - 800 A.D., are archaic, and span into the early part of the millennium, it seems possible these were names of Khasa chiefs without inherited rule. The first set of names have no obvious connection to each other and may not form part of a dynasty or lineage. They may in fact be mythical or deified names with which to begin the vamsavali. At this period there is no direct evidence on labor history except that social stratification had deified local rulers. The migration of Rajputs into the region is unlikely at this time and the kings are likely Magar or indigenous local inhabitants. 91 The early local kings might have given fealty to one of the great dynastic traditions to the east (Kirati and later Licchavi) or west (Katyuri and Gupta dynasties). Bishop (1990) speculates that local rulers gave tribute to Katyuri princes in Kumaon who in turn gave tribute to Gupta kings.ii Which grains were commonly used in the Bheri river area at the beginning of this political formation is unknown but would be an important means of revenue for a newly formed state society. Wheat, millet, barley, lentil and rice were domesticated grain varieties which were part of the plant economy in surrounding areas by 4000 B.P. (Vishnu Mittre, 1977; Riley, Mateo et al. 1990).. Corn and potatoes were introduced by about 1600 A.D. (Rhoades 1990). Indeed, in some parts of Jajarkot potato growing has only taken root within the last twenty years.iii B. Bishop writes that maize was introduced in the Karnali region thirty to forty years ago.iv Gupta influences may have impacted on the Jajarkot region. Bishop places the Jajarkot region under the peripheral domain of the Katyuri [Katuris] princedoms and their Khasa ancestors during this era (1990:66-67). As Adhikary demonstrates, "In the copper plate grants of Lalitashur (835 A.D.), Padmatdev (945), and Suviksaraj (circa A.D. 980) the Khasas are mentioned as the principal subjects of the Kumaon Kingdom. During the rule of Katuris, the Khasas formed the dominating bulk of the society of Kumaon." Brahma (#1) to Dewasar (#43), may have patronized the Katyuri and/or Guptas with land based in-kind revenues such as grain in return for their promise to allow Jajarkot rulers autonomy in everyday business. The region now comprising Jajarkot was probably not a vassal to the Licchavi Dynasty (3th - mid 7th c.) in the Kathmandu Valley. The Licchavi borders probably extended west to the Gandaki River (R. Shaha, 1988:165-66). The Gupta empire used an indirect method of revenue collection, such that they would appoint local collectors or simply use the power bases already in place in distant 92 places such as Jajarkot to receive revenues. This system, known as jimmawala revenue collection, has been in place ‘since the beginning’. The 'decentralized' form of government in early India has been described by A. Southall as a 'segmentary state system' in which "the range of ritual suzerainty and political sovereignty do not coincide. The former extends widely towards a periphery which is flexible and changing. The latter is confined to the central, core domain." (unpubl. ms:1). B. Stein (1980) used the idea of segmentary state systems in his analysis of South Indian empires, the Cilapadikaram (2nd C. A.D.) through the Vijayanagara (ending circa 1800). The "das" lineage is modified into other names for a few generation (#43-46; until possible 1050 A.D.). Subsequently, the Malla lineage becomes dominant. The Malla lineage begins possibly with Golas, Raja #51 (if he came from Gelas, located one or two days' walk southwest of Jumla's capital of Sinja), and would be part of the Malla power structure operant at the beginning of the 12th century. The Jajarkot lineage, however, is distinctly not the same list of Malla rulers found on the famous Dullu pillar (Kirtistambha), which begins with Nagaraja (circa 1200), and continues through Abeyamalla (circa 1378; he erected the pillar). The Dullu pillar is located in Dailekh along the Jajarkot - Dailekh - Jumla walking route, and Dullu was the winter capital of the Khasa Kingdom. Then who are the Jajarkoti Malla rulers, numbers 51-59? And how are they related to the Dullu pillar inscription of Malla royalty? It is probable that the Mallas living in Jajarkot ascribed by Pandit Sharma were Adhiraja or Yubaraja (princes) who didn't succeed to the main line but were tributary related rulers in a segmentary state system of feudal royal relations. Also, ote that the Malla rulers of western Nepal are a distinct set of rulers, with no documented kin-relationship to the Malla rulers of the Kathmandu valley (ca. 13th-18th c.). In fact, the Khasa Mallas invaded the Kathmandu valley seven times, from 1288 - 93 1334 AD, burning and looting various villages, and giving prayer to the Hindu and Buddhist shrines. They never succeeded in pacifying the inhabitants of the valley, however, under their rule. Jajarkot rulers' obvious close connection to recorded Rajas on the Dullu inscription, with its contingent information on taxation and obligations of various village functionaries, holds important clues to labor relations in medieval Jajarkot. The greater Khasa kingdom and the Jajarkoti lineages in the vamsavali finally coincide with Kings Jayabhamma and Malaibhamma (1378-92 A.D.) when the Khasa kingdom reaches its demise and splinters into the state-kingdoms of Dailekh, Jajarkot, Jumla, Rukum, and Salyan (which today are all political districts within the modern Kingdom of Nepal). This period begins the rise of the Baisi Raja, or twenty-two kingdoms, a period of Khasa state fragmentation. From this point onward in Jajarkoti history, about 1500 A.D., the Shaha family line dominates politics. This periods marks the beginning of early modern laws governing taxation, land tenure, and labor obligations to the Jajarkot state. In the next section, I focus on the Shaha royal era in which Jajarkot was a part of the Baisi Raja, twenty-two kings, a fragmented set of kingdoms dating from about 1400 to 1770 A.D. Documented Evidence of Early Jajarkoti History What the Jajarkot people know of their own written history comes to them in part from Itihas Prakash Mandal, "Light on History" written by an ascetic of the Gorakhanath sect, Yogi Naraharinath (1956, esp. Vol. 2, parts 1-3) and Mechi dekhi Mahakali Vol. 4, historical volumes available in Kathmandu. Many works deal peripherally with history of the Jajarkot region though none take Jajarkoti history and circumstances as a focal point. Histories written in English with references to the region include Adhikary 1988; 94 Tucci 1956:46-68; D. R. Regmi 1965; Petech 1958:102-104; Stiller 1973; Bishop, 1990: 65-80; Pandey 1969; Kirkpatrick, 1975 [1811]: 283, 301; and M. C. Regmi 196982(1972): 7. A good review of Nepalese historiography is R. Shaha 1988 which outlines the relations among the preceding works and others. In Nepali see Bhattarai 1974. The texts shed light on elite political relations extant from the period of about 1200 A.D. to 1950 A. D. Though the texts overtly tell the story of the movements of kings, prime ministers, and nobility, in a covert fashion these may also be read as patrilineal "texts" highlighting political formations and relations of power among elites, though hierarchical relationships with commoners are absent. Below I translate a local scholar’s version of these Mechi dekhi Mahakali. Karki-ji began by roughly reading from Mechi dekhi Mahakali: Translation From Gandaki to Karnali, the state originally contained twenty-two kingdoms including Jajarkot. This kingdom was originally part of the Licchavi kingdom during its reign in history into the Jumla period. The Licchavi kingdom lasts nine hundred years and eventually in west Karnali the Malla and Khashiya (Khasa) became strong. The ruler Nagaraj was strong during this time and books about him are available in histories about northern India as well. When Nagaraj entered Sinja he accomplished many good works and his lineage followed through Chapa, Chapilla, Krasichalla, Kradhichalla, Krachalla, Asokachalla, Jitarimalla, Adhityamalla, Pratapamalla, and so on. Pratapamalla Comments Gandaki and the Karnali are two great rivers running vertically toward India. Gandaki is east of Jajarkot and Karnali is in the far west. From more recent evidence, it appears that Jajarkot was not part of the Licchavi Kingdom circa 3rd-13th C. AD. in Kathmandu/Nepal. The Jumla period refers to Jajarkot's relationship with the Khasiya kings located in Jumla starting about 1200 AD. Nagaraj may have been a Tibetan elite who married into the local elite's family. He is documented in stellae as the founder of the Khasa Kingdom. See Adhikary 1988. Sinja is the summer capital of the Khasa Kingdom (11th-14th c. AD). 95 made Punyamalla and the Malla family line his ancestral successors even though Punyamalla was his daughter's husband because he had no sons and thus he made Punemalla's husband his successor. Their son, Prithivimalla, eventually became King of Jajarkot and the Kingdom grew very strong. In that time the vast Kingdom was composed of Khasiya and Malla lines and it stretched from Gadawal to Trisuli Gandaki and from Taklakot to the terai; Jajarkot was part of the Malla's kingdom. After Prithivimalla, Abheyamalla constituted the last King of the Gela lineage and he reigned from 1391-1393. After Abheya, Medinivarma became Jumla's king. Finally the awesome kingdom of the Mallas was finished. After that time each Raja and his family from each of the areas gained control. At the same time the Mogul invasions were going on and in order to save the Hindu religion and many lives, people came into the hill areas of Nepal. The Rajputs [sons of Indian kings] came to Nepal and settled into the hill areas. They made small kingdoms and therefore the western part of Nepal eventually got divided into what is called the Baisi Raja [the twenty-two kingdom alliance] and the Chaubisa Raja [the twenty-four kingdom alliance]. Jajarkot was one of the Baisi Raja of which there were many lineages. According to the Saimal bangsa [the Saimal family lineage], the King of the Saimal family, Malaibamma, had four sons. One of the sons, Jagati Siøha was the King of Jaktipur and Jajarkot. There are remains of the kingdom to this day in Punemalla is the daughter of the king and her husband became king. He is known as Punyamalla (Adhikary 1988). Prithivi broke from the greater Khasa Kingdom and declared Jajarkot a separate kingdom. This is the beginning of the fragmentation of the Khasa Kingdom into the twenty-two kingdoms of which Jajarkot is one. Gadawal is in India; Trisuli is in eastcentral Nepal; Taklakot is on the TibetNepal border. People theorize that the Magar ethnic groups were in the Jajarkot region first. Then the Khasas came and reigned through the Khasa kingdom. Then Thakurs or Rajputs came to avoid the Moguls. When low castes came is not mentioned. Some people say they came with the Thakurs. The Shaha ruling lineage claims to be of Thakuri - Rajput heritage. 96 Jaktipur. Karkiji translated to me in simple English and Nepali as we sat on the ågan or front enclosure of the house. He continued partially translating and adding bits of his own historical recollections. The following is thus a combination of his own Jajarkoti historical version mixed with the standard printed version in Mechi dekhi Mahakali: Translation No one has done research about the history of Jajarkot and thus there is no decision about when the Kingdom at Jaktipur was established. Once Jagati Siøha said to Baliraj, "Do you want to take Jajarkot?' and so we think that this time, 1398 - 1404 A.D. is possibly the time of their rule and when Jagatisiøha made Jaktipur his capitol. According to the local people, the King's horse came to graze at Jajarkot. The King came to get the horse and saw that it was a good place. His grandson liked this place better than Jaktipur and therefore the capitol was moved to Jajarkot. Since he was so great, they think that Jagatisiøha went to a holy place in India and never returned. He became a "saint" [Nep: lob]. Jayasiøha was the son of Jagatisiøha and after Jaya there were 18 generations. Finally Hari Bikram Shaha [HBS] then became King. At this time in Nepal, Prithivi Narayan Shaha [PNS] was the King of Gorkha. HBS went to Benares [Varanasi] and met PNS in 1743 A.D. PNS and HBS made an agreement that they wouldn't invade each other. They vowed on the water at Varanasi. PNS considered the Chaubisa Raja in Gandaki and Bagmati. He thought about those kingdoms on the west of the Gandaki and he was afraid that they would attack him. After HBS, Gajendra Bikram Shaha [GBS] became King [of Jajarkot]. GBS kept good relations with PNS during the time that PNS conquered Kantipur when Jaya Prakas Malla was King of Kathmandu. Comments Jagati Siøha (or, Jaktisingh Malla) was a King in the region. Baliraj was possibly a prime minister. Jagati Siøha seceded from the Khasa kingdom. Then GBS sent two men to Kathmandu with horses, a turban, blankets, musk deer, and gold coin as gifts. PNS The far west remained to conquer for PNS. The PNS unified the whole of Nepal. He came from Gorkha District near Pokhara. PNS invaded Kathmandu valley and the western Rajas. PNS attacked the Chaubisa Raja, a set of twenty-four kingdoms in the west near the Gandaki river. 97 sent a letter to Gajendra warning him ahead of time that if Jajarkot King aligned with they [PNS] were successful at Bijepur and Chaudandi he the new King of [PNS] would attack to the western side. PNS asked that Kathmandu. Gajendra align with him and report to PNS about the fort strengths and weapons of the other twenty-one kingdoms in the Baisi Raja. PNS promised that if he were victorious over both the Chaubisa Raja and the Baisi Raja he will not attack Jajarkot and GBS his line may keep their succession and kingdom. Gajendra could keep the right to execute anyone, he could shave anyone's head, he could take or give a person's jat [caste status], and keep the rights of birta (to give state lands and collect taxes), take lands (jagga harnu), keep lands of people who die with no inheritors. If another king succeeds the old, he should give [salami: tribute] Rs. 701 [to the Gorkha king]. So PNS attacked the Chaubisa Raja and the Baisi Raja except for Jajarkot. Afraid that while he attacked the Chaubisa Raja , the Baisi Raja would attack him, PNS married his daughter to the son of the King of Sallyan. In 1843 A.D., Kaji Jiv Shahi, Parat Bhandari, Jog Malla, and Chammu Bhandari came as ambassadors of PNS and met King Gajendra at Agarikot. Sallyan is part of the Baisi Raja. Agarikot is near the Bheri river, the present day suspension bridge, and the town of Pul in Rukum District. They carried news that PNS won't do harm to Jajarkot and they made an agreement. The agreement said that many generations will continue under the Jajarkot kings' lineage and will be under the Gorkha kings' rule. To witness the agreement they had a puja with a Bahun, cows, janai [sacred thread], tulasi leaves, salygram [a soft stone] and they made the agreement before these sacred things. Ram Bahadur Shaha and Nayab Bahadur Shaha also kept RBS and NBS are the heirs the agreement. According to their agreement, King of Prithivi Narayan Shaha. Gajendra sent news to the Gorkha King that the Kings of Doti and Accham had abdicated from their thrones. Then Gajendra went to Doti and Accham and conquered those states. Rana Bahadur Shaha was pleased and a marriage was arranged between Gajendra's son's [Indra Narayan] daughter [Durga Kumari] to Rana Bahadur Shaha's son, Dip Narayan. 98 [One important event in Jajarkot during this time was that] Durga Kumari wrote to Rajendra Bikram Shaha and said that 'Jajarkot's climate was bad, everyone has goiters, to please give us Chaurjahari [the plains area to the south of Jajarkot now lying in Rukum District]. Durga Kumari was King Rajendra's aunt and in 1834 B.S. she got 100 ropani of khet from Rajendra near Hable and Gotame gaun. ... In India Bal Ram Pur was Raja and the Jajarkot Raja, JBS, changed turbans with Bal Ram in order to confirm their good relations. After this JBS got the villages of Nanaker and Balpur from the Indian Raja in the sense that he became the Jamindari [landlord]. JBS's son, Hari Prakash Shaha, died without becoming King and thus HPS's young son, Narendra Bikram Shaha, became King. After NBS, Upendra B. Shaha became King and he died in 1951 on Kartik 28. The royal family of Jajarkot, HBS's daughter, Bal Kumari, married the Rana Prime Minister, Chandra Samser Rana. Bal Kumari made us a suspension bridge and water tanks and taps in Khalaÿga district. After UBS, Swayam Prakash Bikram Shaha became King [1960/61] and during this time the central government passed a law whereby the Rajas and states lost their powers except for the title of Raja which would remain. SPBS died in Magh (January/February) and Prakash Bikram Shaha became King in 1961 A.D. He now lives in Kathmandu. From time to time Jajarkot [Kingdom] helped the Nepalese government, like the time that Girbana Yuddha Bikram Shaha [King of Nepal] fought the war with England [1814-16 A.D.] or in 1911 B.S. [1857 A.D.] when Nepal fought with Tibet. King Jung Bahadur Shaha of Jajarkot and his brother Brisadhoj went to Thaklakot in Tibet with arms and attacked. Durga petitioned RBS who was king of Nepal by this time. "Hable" and "Gotame gaun" are in Rukum District. The Rana prime ministers were the de facto rulers of Nepal from mid-nineteenth century to 1950 AD. The Kathmandu Shaha Kings were kept out of important politics by the Ranas. King of Jajarkot Jung Bahadur Shaha had at least 2 brothers: Brisadhoj and Juddha Dal. To show respect, it was common for a King's family to name their children after a more At the same time, in 1857 A.D., when India revolted powerful king or prime against England, Jung Bahadur Rana went to Lucknow to minister. This is why a negotiate. At that time Juddha Dal Shaha of Jajarkot, Jajarkot King was named brother of Jung Bahadur Shaha, went to Lucknow with an Jung Bahadur (Shaha). army of 500 to assist Englandv 99 Karki-ji's rendition recounts political history from the position of those in power. His account is interesting in its specificity to the Jajarkot region since all other written accounts refer to larger areas such as Doti state (Pandey, 1970), Karnali region (Bishop, 1990), the Khasas' domains (Adhikary, 1988). Even though Karki-ji's account is mostly taken from written sources it demonstrates a selective gathering of historical texts which become Jajarkot's history seen from an elite viewpoint. Such an historical accounting is not unlike searching for one's family roots from among many library holdings in that the history is public domain and only becomes private as the individual, in this case Karki-ji, reworks or creates a historical rendering. While this history is available to a large audience, it was Karki-ji's interaction with the text and interpretation of written events and certainly his embellishments of the textual information of it which gives it specificity and focus. In this text many heroic deeds and alliances are recounted. Although the text mainly alludes to negotiations between the rulers of Jajarkot and those in Kathmandu and India, two women, Durga Kumari and Bal Kumari, act as patronesses for important political events affecting Jajarkot. Durga instigates a major land grab in the lovely fertile plain to the south of Jajarkot. Through marriage to the Prime Minister in Kathmandu Bal Kumari lays the groundwork for the first development projects in Jajarkot, the water tank and suspension bridge. I found the theme of noble women acting as patronesses several times more in other stories about Jajarkoti history. One stone stellae bears the name of a patroness who erected it and received a land grant for her husband (Adhikary 1988). And the right of a woman to divorce (jarivi) is inscribed in early Khasa kingdom stone stellae (Adhikary 1988:81-82). Known to all high caste women, these deeds of Durga Kumari and Bal Kumari provide ideals for women in 100 Jajarkot who are in positions to gift property (bakashpattra), politically maneuver for development contracts, and commission religious monuments. Material Evidence of Early Jajarkoti History The Bahuns and Thakuri high caste elites create a line, a vamsavali, of royal successions which mnemonically marks political changes if not actual social conditions. The monuments in Jajarkot include stone stellae, water catchments and holding tanks, resting sites, temples, copper-plate inscriptions, and small temples (mandir) to the Gods Maäëa. The state's works (stellae, cater catchments, holding tanks, palaces, some resting sites) were probably all built with compulsory unpaid labor which is today called begar, jhara (< sinjali: dhara?), or sramadan. Temples and religious markers were more likely built with donated or voluntary labor, seva. Seva, used during the Khasa rule, today simply means "service," or a donation of labor as sahayog. The first inscription in Jajarkot proper is a copper plate land grant charter in 1389 A.D. declaring that Malayavarma held the title of Maharajadhiraja [great King of Kings]. He was established at Belaspur situated between Dullu and Jajarkot, his summer capital, and Khadachakra, between Raskot and Kalikot Districts west of Jajarkot, as his winter capital. Malayavarma's kingdom was probably established in opposition to Abhayamalla's until Malayavarma captured Adhayamalla's capital in Jumla and placed Jagatisiøha, Jajarkot's future king, as successor. The history of the Khasa [pronounced /Khashiya/ in Jajarkot] is imprecisely documented through stellae and other architectural remains. The following is a highlight of remains in Jajarkot. Stupas: In Jaktipur village are located about 5 structures, "stupas" or miniature temples, similar to ones credited to the Malla era (Sharma 1972). The only readable 101 portion is "Aum ..." written in both Sinjali and Tibetan scripts which appears beneath the opening inscription, now unreadablevii. The stupas are spaced in a radius of about three hundred yards within the village proper. Remaining above a few of the stupas are sun carvings which resemble the "sun" sculptures placed on the top of Jumli stupas. An important exception is that the stupas at Michagaon in Jumla haven't been mentioned as having inscriptions on them (see Bishop, 1990: 82; Adhikary's fig. 18, the temples of Bistabade, Jumla, and figure 21, the stupa of Michagaun in Jumla for an overall depiction of stupa shape and formation). Stellae:Stellae markers are also a common feature in western regions of Jajarkot district. Although their inscriptions have faded, they appear similar to those found throughout the Khasa dynastic region. The stellae in Jajarkot are mostly located along walking routes to Dullu, Dailekh. These were reportedly used to direct soldiers and travelers along the main route. But some stone markers are located in farmers' fields, on hilltops, and in places were some other feature might have been marked, such as drinking water or homes in which to stay overnight. Some stone markers were used for other purposes as well. There are remains of boundary markers boundary markers, edicts, fountains, reservoirs, irrigation conduits, rest stops, royal quarters, commemoratives, and other buildings (Sharma, 1972). Figures 4.1, 4. 2, and 4.3 are located in western Jajarkot and are examples of road markers from the Khasa era. They are called khamba, or pillars, and may signify a cosmic connection between the earth and the sky (Gautam Vajracharya, personal conversation). Water reservoir: The Khasa used a route leading from Jumla, Dailekh, and Jajarkot Districts into Rukum District. Fig. 4.7a and 4.7b is located north of Chaurjahariviii. It is similar in style to classic Khasa water troughs, with distinctive 102 cornicing of stone crossing and a conical rise in height. See Adhikary 1988 figures 3, 4, 7,and 18. This dissertation's Figure 4.7 is similar to a photo of what Bishop calls a "small temple over a spring at Gothi Chaur, 20 km. east of Jumla-Kalanga," (1990:84). The water reservoir in Figure 4.7 was an extension of Khasa dominion into present day Rukum. This implies that trade and communication was controlled by the Khasa kingdom in western Nepal and the route led from the Khasa dual capitals at Sinja in Jumla and Dullu in Dailekh.ix Sculpture and Temples: The sculptures in Figures 4.5 and 4.6 are found in Figure 4.4 of what is today called the temple "Shiva Mandir." It isn't clear whether the present Shiva Mandir originates from the Khasa period, but it has been rebuilt several times. Its main walls are of brick, two domes are made later than a third, and possibly one dome heralds from the Khasa era. For comparison with temples of Khasa period see Adhikary, 1988, Figure 7. Figure 4.6 is the deity Bhairawa and appears similar to Sharma's example (1972:107, at Chaughan Chaur, Planche VIII) in facial design including the cross patterned hair which is turned into a frame, the crown of skullcaps, ornate ëika mark, broad nose, rounded eyes, elongated rectangular mouth, broad face/cheeks. Bhairawa is a fierce looking Tantric deity who often wears snakes for ornamentation (Deep 1993). The Jajarkot figure has snake earrings while the Chaughan Chaur figure appears to have plate or spherical earrings. Only the head of the sculpture is placed into the outer temple wall in the Jajarkot example. Figures 4.5 and 4.6 were fashioned as a frontice or inset for Shiva Mandir. Figure 4.5, another depiction of Shiva, holds a kalasha in the lower left hand, a trident [trisuli] in the upper left, a achamalla in the upper right, and displays a gesture of barada in the lower right. The Shiva Mandir also contains (not pictured here) a 103 sculpture of a Brahma bull. One can make out a hump on the back of the animal which means it may have been made by an Indian or at least in the terai since Brahma bulls are not indigenous to the area. The Mandir also contains two nagas [serpents] guarding the entrance to a sanctuary for puja worship although the sanctum is empty presently (see Figure 4.9). Above the "lintel" is a miniature carving of a temple which depicts a rounded base and two levels above ending in a top piece which are not of Khasa design. The design is fundamentally different from the overall proportions of Shiva Mandir. It represents a miniature structure of some other classic style of temple. It was possibly purchased in India, Varanasi, or the terai since routes to Kathmandu were much more difficult than routes down into the terai. Directly under the temple plate lies a ram's head with fairly long horns and a human or demon face. More serpents surround the ram's head. No one in the region, including the local historian, knew much about the origins of the Shiva Mandir. Overall the style of the Shaivite temple and sculptures appears to be later than the classic Khasa period (circa 13th century) since the figures have lost the ornate and well carved aspects of classic Khasa period and appear more wooden or crude in stance and adornment (Sharma, 1972). The Bhairawa figure is probably dated after the conquest by the Gorkhas since it shows a distinctly Newar-influenced ’Kathmandu’ expression of Bhairawa. The brick used to surround and protect the Shaivite temple suggests a later date than the temples, possibly within the last two hundred years. The temple seen in Figure 4.8 is commonly attributed to the Khasa and their ancestors. These mandir are temples to the kul devta (Jaj: dyota line or clan deity), Maäëax of most Chhetri and some low caste households. Most lower castes and almost all Chhetri and Thakuri name Maäëa and Bhatu Bhairab as their kul devta. The Maäëa deities are reportedly a family of "twelve brothers and assorted sisters, maternal uncles, 104 nephews, daughters, et al." (Bishop, 1990:117-118). Maäëa mandirs are still made and used in the present century. The Maäëa and their nine adopted sisters, the "Durga Bhavani," have values not of Brahmanical theology. The brothers, as well as the sisters are extremely competitive. They do not practice a theory of appropriate caste work, or dharma, according to one's place in society, I hypothesize that the Maäëa deities are an ideological example of the extreme competition among the petty kings and their domains in western Nepal. They also provide a grassroots ideology for commoners, the Chhetri and some low castes, to reject Brahmanical ideals. As Bishop states (1990:117), The subservient bulk of the Khasa (Chhetri and Matwali Chhetri alike) who bore the brunt of the Kalyals' onerous brand of power, were loath to accept either the dharmic dictates or the Brahmanical deities in which those dictates were embodied. In an effort to counter or ameliorate the pressures imposed by the new elite, the Khasa commoners not only marshaled but modified their egalitarian and pragmatic tribal ways, as well as many of the old animistic and Buddhistic beliefs and practices to which they still clung. Worship of Maäëa using local shamans (jhåkri, dhami, pujari, jaiselu) counters Brahmanism by wielding traditions imbued with egalitarianism, competition, and 'tribal' social relations. Most vamsavali and archaeological artifacts attest to the society of elites. Regarding commoners, little is written on stone and copper plate inscriptions. I found one reference to birta tax free land grants given to priests and artisans, indicating that artisans were patronized by rulers: The Kirtistambha states that taxes were exempted to the Brahmanas, Bhiksus (monks), Dharma-bhanakas (preachers), and Sutradharakas (artisans)...they received the tax-exempt lands from the king. (Adhikary 1988:52) 105 The Kirtistambha is a stone stellae with a long inscription written on it. It was found at Dullu, Dailekh District on the route to Jajarkot and is known in English as "The Dullu pillar." It was erected in 1279 AD. by a Khasa king. According to Khasa Kingdom tax rules, there are taxes which infer basic divisions of labor between high and low segments of society, and a flourishing caste system. First, there was a tax on mudalõ, translated by Adhikary as 'women of certain ethnic groups' such as Magar. Second, there was a tax on kut, rental of land, which indicates that the kut system has been in place since at least the 13th century AD. Another tax was called vratavandha, to raise food and gifts for the sacred thread investiture ceremony, indicating the distinction of high "twice born castes." A tax called seva, or "service" existed which was probably compulsory service rendered by the people for state works. Other types of unpaid labor for the state included dhara and ropairo, for construction of water-receptacles and transplanting wet-rice in noblemen's fields. Many stone inscriptions proclaim that a particular Brahman or other type of priest has been granted immunity from all taxes, including being given birta, tax free lands. In addition, there are many types of administrators, from rokaya who are responsible for feeding guests in a village and Karkya who act as secretaries, to princes and ministers. In Jajarkot the ghatbudha, mukhiya, and nayak, three other rural region functionaries, were also responsible for collecting taxes, settling disputes, and entertaining guests. "Karka" is another common epithet for the head of a village. Karka is written on stone stellae in the area. Broadly, it appears that the Khasa kingdom, of which Jajarkot region was one small part, was quite bureaucratized and diversified in tax base. Many of the social relations which exist in Jajarkot today have their origins from the Khasa period (11th - 106 14th c. AD.), though probably not earlier. The following terms which Adhikary finds in early inscriptions have present day meanings: 1. dhara ---> jhara. Obligatory labor to the state. 2. ropairo ---> roparni. Women who plant/transplant rice or other grains for a landlord. 3. seva ---> seva. Service with implication of labor service to the state. 4. Vrata ---> Bart . A reference to the sacred thread investiture ceremony. Most high caste boys go through this ceremony. 5. kut ---> kut. A tenant rents land from landowner. Somewhat like adhiyå sharecropping. 6. brata ---> birta. A form of land tenure. Uncommon (and illegal) in Jajarkot today. 7. muïali ---> muïali. Though not a tax form, this refers to women in general. As mentioned previously, informal labor relations (jajmani, khalo, adhiyå, parima , sahayog, haliya) do not have written legal rules. These practices have common social rules but have not been inscribed or taxed in Jajarkot. Informal labor relations therefore, are difficult to trace in the historical record. Taxes, legal labor obligations, and land tenure rules however do get inscribed in historical documents.xi I venture that for a ruler to write the taxes and legal edicts attests to the presence of a state formation as early as the thirteenth century in Jajarkot. For more information on taxation in medieval Nepal see Adhikary 1986; 1988; Riccardi; 1977; 1989. In addition to written records, another way to learn about the roles of tax collectors, sharecroppers, and free laborers within the last century is to ask elderly people about their early memories of labor relations. In the next section I look at early twentieth century labor relations and the roles of village functionaries. 107 Oral histories of politics of labor relations Bazaar Elites' historical vignettes J. Vansina (1985) points out that political structures shape historical perspective, and in Jajarkot's case, royal history is the dominant orientation. To partially circumvent tales and gossip which are idealized, Vansina recommends listening for parts of stories which conflict with the idealized version: "When...traits or anecdotes run counter to fashion, they should be seen as reliable. These data resisted the trend to idealization [and] we accept it, because it runs counter to the whole hagiology of state. (1985:10708). Some of my favorite storytellers were people from well-to-do backgrounds with social connections to the royal Jajarkoti family as secretaries, accountants, and other educated offices. They provided the most clearly shaped histories, probably because it was in their interest to create the histories in the first place. Contrarily, histories taken from disenfranchised poor, usually low castes, were often broken, loose, sometimes contrary to received history, which is what makes them so interesting. The following excerpt from an account by three educated high caste men gives an event - the building of a suspension bridge - within the context of unpaid labor, jhara, and locates the labor process within hierarchical social relations. I made the appointment with one of the men, Bharat Shaha, to do a biographical interview. He was in his late 70's and had always interested me with his tact, grace, and obvious success in shopkeeping while appearing, and indeed being, helpful and ungreedy in shop affairs. Lek Karki came along to help Bharat recall events and insert important Jajarkoti dates as reference points. Bharat's old friend Dip Karki, past head of District Political representatives, sat in and contributed bits of gossip as well since Dip was also elderly and liked to share memories. Lek was eager to begin the recording session, and began, "In 1952-11-12 (A.D.1894) the Darbar (government square; political center of 108 the village) was made. In 1984 (A.D.1927/28) the bridge was made." Bharat entered the discussion with his memory of the bridge building and our session had begun in earnest. J: How old were you when the bridge was built? You must've been young. B: Oh, no, I don't know. L: If the bridge was built in 1984 [Bikram Samvat], in what year were you born? B: In 1969 (A.D. 1912-13) L: Then you were 15 years old. J: Did you also work on the bridge? B: I didn't work on it. I was an officer [Malik] of labor [kam garaune]. J: What work does the malik do? L: [The malik's work is ] to check that laborers are working well or not...that the mud digging men are working good or not, that the stone carrying men are working well or not. The King of Jajarkot sent him there for such work. We see the stratification of work relations between laborers, represented by 'Gyudale', and officers such as Malik, or overseer, which Bharat represents. Above the kam garaune men (laborers) and malik, stands the king (Raja), the political force that can enforce unpaid labor for projects. Layered underneath the ongoing suspension bridge work laid a form of labor conducted by ferrymen. This work is/was carried out by caste rules and the Rawot castes performed the work whose function would be superseded by the bridge: J: What did the people cross on before the bridge was built? B: [They crossed] in a kisti [a wooden boat] a little ways from the [present] bridge that people cross. J: Did people give money [as a tithe]? B: Yes we gave money. J: How much? B: 25 paisa, one mohar at the maximum [.25 - 1 rupee]. J: What caste was the boatman? B: Rawot 109 J: Was there another person to ferry people from one side to the other? L: The river was big but if there weren't any other men to carry us; we'd have to swim. D: The wood boat was enough so that men could cross by means of boat. J: I heard that there was this one carrying thing [instead of a boat]. L: That is a chinna [gourd] B: A tumba, that is they tied a float on their waist and then the person can't sink. With that thing the floating person can come up off the water. L: They tied a gourd on their waist and then the men only sink below their waist and they swim in the water. If we can't swim then we catch that gourd man and he carries us from one side to the other. The Rawot's work, part of the khalo system, was to transport people across the river. The older system of using gourds tied around the Rawot's waist is still practiced. I have passed by sunny spots along trails by the Bheri river where piles of gourds lay drying in the sun. Occasionally I spot a fisherman in the swift flowing river with gourds hiked up about his chest, floating gracefully down the river. Bharat said that money was given for transportation but there are accounts of people receiving flour for crossing the river, even to this day. Four men said that there are two systems of payment. One is known as khalo and this is for people one knows, for the local people. In khalo the ferryman is paid two or three times per year from the granary of landowners who use this service. For people the ferryman doesn’t know, a second option entails immediate cash or barter payment. Barter is known as bastu binimaya and most people give tobacco, flour, or fruit. The group of elderly men, after reading a previous interviewee's estimate of 50 paisa for a crossing, felt it should be revised to 4 paisa per crossing. They added that high castes sometimes didn’t pay anything at all, especially if they were related to the king of Jajarkot. (G. Rawot, BJ1:18-22; RRS ’93:2b]. 110 Jajarkoti and Gorkhali kings in Kathmandu enforced the system of compulsory labor until legal reforms after 1951. The system of compulsory labor, jhara, in most of Nepal was used for construction of all State projects such as roads, battlements, bridges, transportation of grains, cultivation of royal lands, etc. M. C. Regmi, who wrote a reference volume on land tenure and taxation for Nepal, described compulsory labor systems as having "in fact no restriction on the uses to which it might be put." (1978:504). Essentially, free labor was the right of landlords to extract at least 15 days' labor from tenants and the government had the same right of 15 days' labor from one member of each household. Bharat's description illuminates how people reacted to compulsory labor: J: Which work did you do to construct the bridge? Did you do accounting? B: I oversaw their work. And also I did accounting at that time. ...[edit out material] J: Was your work paid or not? B: They didn't give money. We only kept accounts. J: What accounts did you keep? B: They haven't money, they didn't have any. [The work] was hanseri; it was free [labor].xii J: What do you say in Nepali for free work? L: Hanseri. Hanseri means voluntary service. B: My work was [scheduled] for 15 days but we returned [from the work] after 3 days. The time [period] was for 15 days but in 3 days we finished and came back. J: How did you get free workers? B: Our own villagers worked. J: Did you call them? B: Yes, we called. If we are four [people] then we should do hanseri. J: Did they like to work hanseri? B: Well, that was government orders. From every family they should work 15 days. Every person should do that work. Bharat's hanseri was scheduled for 15 days but he said they completed their work in only 3 days which means that the ideal period of government free labor was 15 days. In reality people were able to shorten their period of labor donation to the State. 111 Labor donations are still given for some projects, such as school and road construction. Most often a broader epithet, sramadan is used to describe labor to the state. In my socioeconomic surveys I found that both high and low caste households donate state labor. Low castes said they donated less time, on average, than high castes. This might be explained by the fact that low castes are often engaged in labor for individual high caste households. Another explanation might be that low castes tend to go to India for about 5 months per year which gives them less time to donate labor. Village functionaries Indigenous labor practices today are the result of past social relations, of elites to commoners, of creditors to debtors, of patrons to clients. In this section I outline some of the conversations I had with villagers who remembered being part of particular productive social relations. One of the most important intra-village social relationships was between the king, his tax collectors, and commoners. The local names for the village functionaries include, but are not limited to, ghatbuda, mukhiya, nayak, talukdar, and katuwal. The Ghatbuda: Traditionally villages had local functionaries, one of which was the ghatbuda, or the village headman. The ghatbuda was responsible for calling meetings, representing the village in intravillage affairs, collecting taxes, and negotiating disputes. The Nepal village elders described the ghatbuda as akin to an administrative officer: "The ghatbuda was like the ïiëëha. He controlled the district and stopped fights and controlled crops." In Jajarkot the Ghatbuda was a local elite, enjoying the patronage of commoners who would sing and dance for him before paying tribute. The Nayak: Other functionaries that dealt with political affairs before 1951 included nayaks and mukhiyasxiii. A nayak was the head male of a region, like a chief 112 or petty king. The nayak had more power than ghatbuda, controlled a larger region, and was described to me as one involved in negotiating disputes and collecting revenues. As J. B. Gharti said, My father came from Pyuthan and we're pure Magar. The pure Magar's duty is to work for other, higher castes (gharti means "ex-slave"). The pure Magar was the servant of influential "big" persons here. The big persons were called nayak and ghatbuda. My father worked for them. I also worked for them. The commoners had many obligations to village functionaries. Commoners delivered to them many types of taxes bound for the elite in the District Center, for example. Although it sounds like nayaks and ghatbudas were high castes sent by the king to local villages, they actually could be any caste, depending on the caste makeup of the village. In J.B.'s village the village functionaries would have been Magar since the dominant group is Magar. The Mukhiya: An important person much like a "Mayor," his duties are overtly to collect taxes on dryland (in grain payments) but covertly his duties were political. Mukhiyas had a considerable volume of political capital. In another Magar village closer to the District Center, I asked two old men, one a traditional cotton cloth weaver [tetwa cloth maker, represented by "T" below] and the other the village Mukhiya, about their most important past political functionaries. They thought that the mukhiya, katuwal, and nayak were the most important people in their village. About the mukhiya, I asked J: Who was the mukhiya at that time?xiv T: Here we have Magar and in some other places nearby there are Kami [mukhiya ]. J: Was the mukhiya powerful? T: Ho ["Yes"], he was powerful. J: Why was he powerful? 113 T: He meets with people...he adjudicates, he hears local court cases, and he prevents people from fighting. J: Hm. Does he give people loans? T: He used to, he did before. He lent millet all year long, he feeds people, he was a real active working kind of Mukhiya. Other: He was a work leader [now everybody's talking]...The mukhiya used to find people lots of work... T: But thesedays he's losing [his influence] and he doesn't have much work to do. The Katuwal: In addition to ghatbuda and mukhiyas the Katuwal was very influential. There is a myth about a katuwal who usurps a Brahman's land in Chapter Eight. The katuwal role has changed over the centuries. Before 1900 the katwal was quite influential and the role was held by a high caste. The Katuwal's duty was to a particular area of the king's land. He was supposed to watch the forests and agricultural regions to make sure powerful landlords did not try to avoid taxes or adjudication. By 1950 however, a Police officer, Legal court office, and HMG administrators had all but replaced the katuwal's functions. Today the katuwal works as a village messenger. He sends messages from one household to others, from one village to others, and from the elite to commoners or village administrators. For example, the katuwal in Somdada village sent word to all households that Rupa, a Magar friend, and I were setting corn stalks on a particular rather high plot of land and needed at least 3 people to volunteer labor using the indigenous labor practices of either sahayog or parima . Shortly after, workers arrived to help. Rupa and I could not have gone about to all the households and therefore the katuwal's work was appreciated. The katuwal in each village received a portion of each household's grain harvest using the system of khalo. In the villages I visited mainly a low caste hold the position of messenger. Today other means of communication are common, such as letters and shortwave radio. Yet in India the migrants still use the katuwal. In the Nainatal region I met 114 Nepalese migrants who said they paid their local Nainatal katuwal to spread word of jobs available, contractors to contact, labor managers to meet. They all said they paid in grain when they returned each spring to Jajarkot. In general the head village functionary, whether a mukhiya , nayak, or ghatbuda, or talukdar collected taxes on the khet lands and kept 5% of his receipts. Another could take his place if someone challenged him and pledged to collect more taxes than the incumbent. The Nepali elders described their mukhiya as someone who testified, defended, and gave evidence in court about land disputes. They even said that the mukhiya decided local disputes about land. Irrigated lands were quite valuable and even minor disputes could cause people to need an adjudicator.xv The mukhiya’s other important function was to give in-kind loans (anajko riÿ ). In Jajarkot these carry a higher interest rate, about 33% per annum, than cash loans. Jajarkot 's use of village functionaries and tax collectors was unique in several ways from other Districts. M. C. Regmi notes (1978a:46), In the majority of cases [Districts] the only [homesteading] tax retained was the saune fagu, but occasionally a few other taxes, such as walak at five per cent of the serma tax, and magjin at Rs. .32 per homestead...have been continued. It is only in Jajarkot that all the existing taxes, such as bethi, chhalahi, megjin, futkar, and asmanixvi were retained. Until 1954, the Jajarkoti Raja continued his rights as a petty king, including collecting taxes and granting lands (birta). Unlike other regions of Nepal, the king used almost solely Raikar land tenure. Under raikar, the state is the landlord and can collect revenue from tenants and landholders who rent to tenants. Jajarkot did not use the tax collector known as jimmawal, who was closely associated with raikar land tenure in other parts of Nepal. In Jajarkot, mukhiya, ghatbuda, nayak, and talukdar collected revenues. In Jajarkot guthi (religious land grants) and kipat (tribal communal land grants) did not exist though there are references during the Khasa era of guthi land. 115 This is because, unlike the Kathmandu valley and east Nepal, there were no Newars or communal ethnic groups such as Rai and Limbu who traditionally held guthi or kipat. Jajarkot also had no Jagir tenured land, lands granted to HMG government officers in lieu of cash wages. Since there were no government officers until the turn of the century HMG officers were paid in cash wages after 1900. Since government offices in Jajarkot didn’t begin until about 1933, there were no officials to grant jagir lands. The system of land granting, called Birta, existed but was uncommon in Jajarkot.xvii My informants described a birtawal as one who owns or holds birta (land grant) and they said people can give their raikar to a relative using the government named land tenure called birta. Then the person doesn’t have to pay taxes to the state, but on the down side, the person doesn’t own the land anymore either! But they couldn’t remember even one case of birta, and these informants included the school administrator, the local historian, the ex-chair of the National Panchayat, and a Mukhiya. It seems the Jajarkot king did not grant lands to his officers, such as the royal messenger (katuwal), the tax collector (talukdar), and the administrative officer (ïiëëha), at least during the last century, but paid them in cash and food or grain. In Khasa era inscriptions, however, birta tax free land grants are recorded. They were given to various Brahmans, priests, and artisans. Taxes: The Material Relationship between Nobility and Commoner Taxation in kind Besides labor donation legally set at 15 days per annum in the jhara system of unpaid labor obligations, informants talked about the taxes they had to give to the king's collectors.xviii Money was not much used in the early twentieth century A.D. Tax collectors, (talukdar, mukhiya, etc.), collected whatever produce was available in each village. According to one informant, collectors took any agricultural surplus [napha, lit.: profit] villagers could produce. In a discussion with a tetwa maker and the village 116 head in the Magar village of Chiurigaù, they said they used to give millet, curd, ghiu (ghee), maize, chiuri oil, and even wild yams collected in the forest. Of course the official basis of tax assessment varied across Nepal. In Jajarkot assessment on agricultural land was by the adhiyå system. Half of the harvest goes to the landlord or state and half to the cultivator.xix Village taxes, head taxes, gun taxes, and other non-agricultural taxes were collected by village functionaries. Rural villagers more than three hours' from the District Capital often avoided the adhiyå system of giving one half their production to the headman. Rural villagers were not considered direct tenants on the king's land. Instead they had to give a negotiated amount to the collectors. In Chiuri Gaun, for example, up to a dharni, 2.4 Kilos of each product was given. Transition to taxation in cash By 1938 a tax office was installed in Jajarkot by HMG which superseded tax collection by the Jajarkot King. Taxes on khet lands were low given the value of the rupee in 1938 but combined with other cash taxes, the cash assessments per household were enough to force households to seek some form of employment or production which would generate a cash income. While assessment was levied in rupees, actual payment in the hills areas was payable in grain. 4.2: 1938 assessments on Khet (irrigated) lands in Jajarkot Grade Abal(top) Doyam(medium) Sim(medium-low) Chahar(low) Cold Zone Rs. 0.27 Rs. 0.21 Rs. 0.12 Rs. 0.09 *Rupees per muri of produce M.C. Regmi, 1978:96 Warm Zone Rs. 0.28 Rs. 0.22 Rs. 0.13 Rs. 0.13 117 The 1963 (2021 B.S.) Finance Act made irrigated land assessments similar for all hill districts and set the rate at the following: Table 4.3: 1963 Assessments of irrigated land Grade Rupees Abal 0.65 Doyam 0.55 Sim 0.45 Chahar 0.35 Bhiralo (steep)0.60 (later reduced to 0.35) M.C. Regmi, 1978:810 and Jajarkot informants concerning Bhiralo graded land. In-kind assessment was not possible in Jajarkot after 1963 and cash only was collected. Rural inhabitants had to find ways to sell their produce even when the DC didn't have a weekly bazaar and few government offices or tea stallsxx. Most small farmers owned pakho, unirrigated lands, and the change to an obligatory cash tax had more impact on small and marginal farmers. In Jajarkot, wealthier farmers who own irrigated land were more likely to recruit tenants (mohi). Wealthy farmers even used cash to offset construction costs of irrigation systems [kulo]. In 1963 unirrigated lands had not been land surveyed. Rates for pakho were measured in the hal, amount of land a plow team could work in a day, or bij, amount of seed broadcast on a unit of land: Table 4.4: 1963 Assessments of Pakho land Name Description Assessment (Rupees) hale land which can be plowed 3.0 Pate difficult to plough; rain washed soil 1.5 Kodale only spades can be used 0.75 Kute only a small piece of land 0.50 ? Bijan sow by handful or mana of seed 0.15 Bijan reduced to 0.11 per mana in 1964) M.C. Regmi, 1978:810xxi with Jajarkot informants *Jajarkot most often used the Bijan system. 118 Additional taxes In Jajarkot, the tax office, Mal Adalit, was established circa 1932 and from that time taxes were more frequently levied in cash. There are various money taxes on nonagricultural products and production. Maskarinec (1990:64) remarked that by 1989 taxes on government supervised alcohol and tobacco created the largest tax revenues for HMG. The local government office (gaun Panchayat in 1987) collects several types of taxes. They tax water mills (pani ghaëëa) based on how many months per year the mill operates. Houses are taxed, radios by law should be taxed, and most guns can also be taxed. Any cash taxes or transactions are significant since many rural households have low cash flows. Between 1939 and 1945 goods became expensive and people began to earn more money than they had previously. Still, tax laws in Jajarkot were not enforced. In reality, people paid far less than the taxes listed in the Tables above. One reason is because in Jajarkot no one had surveyed the lands and there was little way to know how much land officially someone owned. The rashid or land certificate included information on the landholder’s name, the name of the land parcel, its chhetraphal or number, and a statement of quality (abol, sim, etc.). Tax collectors generally took the people’s bacheko or napha meaning their agricultural leftovers or surplus rather than taking any specified amount in cash. Most of this surplus went to the Jajarkoti King with a smaller portion kept aside for the local functionaries. Concluding Remarks In Chapter Four I have tried to make three points. First, the social organization of indigenous labor has roots in Jajarkot's early state formations, especially noticeable in 119 the Khasa era, 12th - 14th centuries. From this era there come the first written records for the area. The first allusions to patronage are attested to on stone stellae. The first mention of compulsory labor to the state is listed, called seva and dhara, terms still in use today. The first birta, tax free land grants are described in stone stellae and copperplates. The first statements come to light that jari, women's divorce rights, are practiced, as they are today. And a complex list of taxes and tributary obligations is inscribed for later generations to emulate. A second point in this Chapter is that elite renditions of history, embodied in vamsavali, cannot tell commoner history. Since commoners are by definition illiterate, oral histories are very important. The stories commoners tell of the past may sometimes not seem like histories, but slowly we are learning to incorporate these 'evening tales' into more rounded understandings of the past social organization of labor. Even though some of today's indigenous labor practices in Jajarkot have roots dating to a medieval Khasa reign, labor has changed immensely in the twentieth century. And we have scant evidence of past centuries so we cannot judge social change previously in Jajarkot. In the twentieth century the political structure shifted from Kingdom to partyless Panchayat to democracy. The economic organization shifted from emphasis on patronage and in-kind exchange toward capitalism and money exchange. Social organization is also shifting from the prominence of indigenous practices to an emphasis on introduced practices. Yet the shifts are neither monolithic nor onedirectional. In the next three chapters it is to these indigenous labor practices I turn. While the following indigenous labor practices were not inscribed on stone for us to compare with today's practices, still they are part of the network of labor relations which were recorded, the land tenure laws, tax laws, and labor obligations to the state. 120 Moving out of a historical background I will now examine the mechanics and social background of patronage (khalo, jajmani), casual labor (baure), loans (riÿ), bonded labor (hali), reciprocity (parima), and gifts of labor (sahayog). N otes to Chapter Four iAn English source on Nepali government documents is housed in the Regmi Research Series (Regmi, M.C. 1969-1986), a collection of translated laws, announcements, tax records, and other records. ii The Pala family, from circa 800-1100 AD, ruled in greater western Nepal but in the Jãjarkoë lineage, there is no connection with Pala names. The earliest set of obviously kin-related rulers begins with the /-dãs or Dãs-/ names, starting at Dãsarath (ruler #33) with an estimated date of 790 A.D. The /dãs/ lineage (rulers # 33-42) may have been under the influence of the Gupta empire: "...the Gupta dynasty held paramount power over all of northern India, exacting tribute from these mountain states [western Nepal, Kumaon, Garhwal] as well as from the tribal republics of Rajasthan." [Bishop, 1990:69]. iii R. Rhodes points out that in the Kathmandu valley, potatoes have been a cultivar since perhaps before 1773 A. D. (1990:293). In western Jajarkot, I heard of potatoes being cultivated merely twenty years ago, when a foreigner brought them into the remote area. Keep in mind that one of the first Europeans to walk into Jãjarkoë was David Snellgrove in 1956. iv B. Bishop on introduction of corn (1990:213): "At the regional scale it [corn] ranks first in importance only in the broad Chaudhãbisã Valley of economic region D [Karnãli Zone] where informants report that it was introduced thirt to forty years ago. This agrees with information from informants in Jãjarkoë. Bishop also notes a unique practice of corn cultivation: "During the second weeding several roots are severed and the plant bent in a manner that permits it to continue to grow upright as the remaining roots penetrate to a greater depth. The cultivators believe that this practice improves yields and reduces the changes of drought-induced crop failure." (1990:213). This practice is called dalnu, "to set" the stalk, and is common in Jãjarkoë maize production. v JBR used Jãjarkoë's armies to assist the British in Gorakhpur and Lucknow with 8,000 troops who were aligned with Britain. [Thapa 1967:118; Moreland and Chatterjee 1966:366] . vi An innacurate translation of jãri is "adultery." vii Another Stupa reads "Om Mane Padme Hù" but is only readable because this is a common salutation. viii I couldn’t find out what patron built the surrounding wall within the last century. The small temple has an orifice or inner sanctum just above the main platform. Inside the temple there is presently a lingum and chalk drawing of a trident. Whether the temple was originally Hindu is unknown but it may have changed over the centuries as the Khasa became 121 Hinduized. The temple also may have been multipurpose: to mark a stream and act as place of ritual supplication. ix Jãjarkoë kings also had a system of dual capitals. In the warm wet summer months the raja was able to move to the summer palace at Ramidãda, north Jãjarkot. A Jãjarkoë king built an open air water tank, about 11' x 20' on a natural spring. The tank is sacred and used by dhãmis and jhånkris to bathe before the panch purni melã [the fifth full moon fair] in asoj/cartik. x For works relating to the Maäëã deities, for Jãjarkoë particularly see Maskarinec 1990. See also Campbell 1978; Y. Naraharinath 1956; Tucci 1956; Snellgrove and Richardson 1961; Gaborieau 1969; and Shrestha B. S. 2028:91-104. xi In Nepal the best source of information on taxes and labor relations is M. C. Regmi 1978. Other good sources of general information include S. Adhikary 1988 and B. Bishop 1990. For comparison with classic Indian rules of taxation and labor relations, I have used especially L. N. Rangarãjãn 1992. xii IBS said he used the term hanseri but the common term in Jãjarkoë is known as jhara or begãr. xiii xiv Naikes are used as guards in forests in recent times but historically were also tax collectors and reported new agricultural lands to the King. M.C. Regmi cites a 1807 document concerning a Naike at Dullu in the heart of the Khasa enclaves " 'to take care of military stores...bring land under cultivation, and function as tax collector on Khet land'..." [1978:127]. In 1900 Pali consisted of only 12 houses. Pali village now has about 110 houses in the greater village area extending down to the river and off to the flanking hills. xv There was no village functionary known as jimmãwãl in Jãjarkoë. xvi These are types of homesteading taxes. xvii Birtã is different than in India since Birtã lands were inherited rather than commuted at the death of the grantee. Thus in Nepal Birtã tended to accumulate over generations. xviii Beth and Begar are two other forms of unpaid labor obligations described by M.C. Regmi 1969-86 Volumes (14):50 and (15):36; 1978. xix For discussion on taxes in relation to land issues see M.C. Regmi, 1978 and the Regmi Research Series, 1969-1986. xx Tea stalls were illegal before 1950 according to G. Maskarinec (1990). xxi Pate = 1/2 a hale Kodãle = amount of land a kodale, iron spade, can prepare in a day. 43 5 Khalo, jajmani, and rin-din as expressions of paternalism -Khalo (patronage) is for people one knows, local people. Paisã (money) and bastu binimãyã (barter) are for the other people. -Y. Karki, M.B. Shaha, B.B. Karki, and I.B. Shaha Broadly, the protection, authority, and claim to certain rights over an individual constitutes patronage. The practice has been known since at least Roman times, evidenced by the use of "patronus," cognate of "pater," (father). Patronage has taken specific forms in different societies and eras. Patronage within the Roman empire was qualitatively different than patronage during Charlemagne's reign, and different from patronage in South Asian casteorganized societies. In this Chapter I will discuss khalo, jajmani, and lending (rin-din ). I argue that patronage is often created using khalo, jajmani, and rin-din . Khalo and jajmani are not perfectly overlapping cultural constructs of patronage, however. Khalo and jajmani may be simply acts of exchange based on long-standing relationships between service specialists and agriculturalists. But hierarchical socioeconomic conditions combined with khalo and jajmani create an environment for patronage. Caste position, landholding size, education level, creditor/debtor status, income, and geographical location are factors in the creation of patronage. When combined with these socioeconomic conditions, khalo and jajmani become mechanisms of unequal exchange in a system of patronage. In Part One of Chapter Five I stress that jajmani and khalo are not degrading in this agricultural region of 100,000 people. Instead they form part of an efficient network of noncapitalist labor relations. As evidence, I present information on socioeconomic conditions 44 surrounding khalo and jajmani. I outline the various caste specialists in Jãjarkot, give information on khalo grain payments to artisans, and examine landholdings of each caste by geographical regions in Jãjarkot. I conclude this section by presenting a correlation of categories (landlord, employer, patron, artisan, tenant, laborer) from my Peripheral Region Survey which examines lending patterns and other economic activity by category. In Part Two of this Chapter I find that interaction of introduced credit (bank loans) and indigenous credit (rin-din ) actually reinforces a system of patronage. In general, the elite segments of society, including landlords, employers, and patrons, tend to take bank loans and at the same time tend to give out indigenous loans. Artisans, tenants, and laborers, conversely, tend to take indigenous loans and avoid dealing with bank loans. These lending patterns importantly also display the interaction of capitalist and paternal production forms. As evidence, I explore the lending patterns of households in particular labor categories. I conclude that "Patrons" tend to take introduced credit from banks and channel their own resources to poorer neighbors by means of indigenous loans. The World of Khalo, Jajmani, and Patronage in Jãjarkot Many low caste families, almost half, support themselves with artisanal work while the other low caste households take up unskilled labor such as portering and agricultural labor. Traditional artisanal caste duties in Jãjarkot include ironsmithing, tailoring, leatherworking, pottery making, prostitution, playing particular instruments, washing, dancing, singing. Several artisanal castes combine more than one duty. Other duties devolve upon one caste but are not hereditary. Bãdi households, for example, make clay pipes in addition to dancing, singing, and prostitution. Bãhun families in Jãjarkot often do not serve as priests. It may have been that someone in their patriline married a lower caste woman, or that a forefather could not compete with neighboring priests for clients. Of the twenty four Bãhun households in my surveys (DCS, 45 PRS, RRS and LRS) only six families provide priestly services. Four eastern Jãjarkoti villages in the surveys, predominantly Magar, had no Bãhun households. These villages rely for ritual and medical services mainly on dhãmi and jhånkri indigenous healers. Of the priest households I interviewed, each had over 100 clients. They travel in a one or two day range of villages to conduct their services. The table below outlines the various types of caste duties in Jãjarkot. 46 [insert table about here] 47 Common Thar Names in Jãjarkot High Castes Bãhun: Uphadhaya are pure or highest status Bãhuns and Jaisi are lower status because they have a marriage somewhere in their lineage with a non-Bãhun family. In Jãjarkot the following thar or patrilineal clans include: Acharya, Adhikari, Baral, Baskota, Bhatta, Bhattarai, Bistã, Brahmacharya, Devkota, Gautam, Hamal, Jaisi, Khanal, Koirala, Pande, Pandit, Pantha, Pokharyal, Regmi, Samal, Sharma Sanyãsi: Families related from men who were originally religious mendicants and usually Bãhuns but who returned from retreat to become householders. I tabulated this group with Bãhun in statistical descriptions. In Jãjarkot the following thar are found: Giri, Nath, Yogi Thãkuri (Or Rãjput): Originally of Khasa descent, these thar trace ancestry to the royalty of the Malla Kingdom in western Nepal. In Jãjarkot the following thar or clans are found: Hamal, Malla, Shaha, Shahi, Singha, Thãkuri Chhetri: These families either are tagadari or twice born thread wearing, or fall below the tagadari status and are labelled Matwali drinking caste Chhetri. It is not possible to tell this status from the thar name. In Jãjarkot the following thar or clans are found: Adhikari, Basnet, Bhandari, Bhatala, Bistã, Bohara, Budha, Budha Thapa, Budhatheki, Chhetri, Dhãmi, Dharala, Karki, Kasera, Khadaka, Khatri, Mahat, Rana, Rawol, Rawot, Rokaya, Samal, Thapa, Gharti-Chhetri 48 Magar: Families descended from an ethnic group which preceded the infiltration of Khasa groups from the west. In Jãjarkot all Magar speak Nepali and generally practice matrilateral cross cousin marriage within Jãjarkot and Rukum districts. There are some words still used from the Kham language. Most Magar families are located in all parts of the district except the west. In Jãjarkot the following thar are found: Budha, Thapa Gharti, Ghartii, Jhankri, Ulunge Pun, Ranaji Pun, Rana, Thapa Newar: Most Newar came out from Kathmandu about three generations ago when the first government offices opened and the Kathmandu government sent Newars with officials to the bazaar. In Jãjarkot the following thar are found: Bhadel, Bhandari, Shakya, Shrestha Low Castes Many low castes used the last name "Nepali" during interviews. While there are caste clans, low castes tend to intermarry. The caste name of the father was given to me as the clan name even if a person's mother is of another caste. Kãmi: Kãmi are a metalworking caste which is generally associated with ironsmithing. Kãmi families generally live on the outskirts of villages in the rural regions. Most families engage in unskilled labor and sometimes skilled construction as well. In Jãjarkot the following thar are found: Bisokarma, Chandara, Dangi, lohãr, Nepali, Wãr 49 Sunãr: A goldsmithing caste. Although there are thar, clans were reckoned to me by first and last name of the ancestor and the last name was always "Sunãr". Tomãtto: A copper or brass working caste. Although there are thar, clans were reckoned to me by first and last name of the ancestor and the last name was always "Tomãtto". Sãrki: Although there are thar, clans were reckoned to me by first and last name of the ancestor and the last name was always "Sãrki". Damãi: Although there are thar, clans were reckoned to me by first and last name of the ancestor and the last name was always "Damãi". Bãdi: Although there are thar, clans were reckoned to me by first and last name of the ancestor and the last name was always "Bãdi". Payments and Services of Artisans Payment for artisanal services is generally made in the form of grain. Of the 117 Peripheral Region Survey respondents who said they gave khalo payments, the average khalo payment of grain per year was 82.80 kg. The maximum khalo payment in kilos grain per year was given as 188 kg. The minimum khalo payment in kilos grain per year was given as 37 kg. The standard deviation among surveys amounted to 59.34 kg. The variation of about 60 kilograms of grain among households which give khalo is mainly a result of the size of families, how much they depend on the artisan's services, and how much grain the agriculturist harvests. Small families (with less land and less need for artisans) give the smallest khalo payments. The ironsmith, tailor, and goldsmith are by far the most common khalo recipients. Musicians, pipe makers, 50 coppersmiths and potters occasionally use khalo arrangements and usually take cash payment. The Bãhun priest receives sida ("portion," not khalo), from his jajãmãn (not bistã) several times per year, often immediately after his services. The sida is often also given to the priest as part of the funeral gifts of a patron. Unlike traditional literatures on jajmani in India, people in Jãjarkot make a distinction between the services of the Bãhun and those of artisans. Like their Indian counterparts, the duties of artisans and priests are similar. Artisans serve as musicians for marriages and celebrations, they sometimes serve their bistã patrons in small requests, and they provide artisanal services in exchange for semi-annual grain payments. Some artisans in the District Center have successfully switched to solely cash payments and they do not use the khalo system. These artisans have mostly migrated into Jãjarkot from neighboring Districts. Ganesh Sãrki, for example, arrived from Surkhet District Center at a melã or fair on the Bheri River in Jãjarkot during the summer of 1990. He walked with our crowd of friends back to the Bazaar (Jãjarkot District Center has a small Bazaar) and asked a Newãr shopkeeper to loan him a space to set up a shoe repair stall. For a couple of rupees, depending on the work, the leather worker fixed rubber chapals (sandals) and leather goods. Another Sãrki, a master craftsman who migrated in from Surkhet, hooked up with a local NGO which promotes sustainable agriculture. The Master is training a local Sãrki whose father left the profession. They are importing leather from India, copying the latest shoe fashions, and incorporating a local hemp for stylistic variations. The workmanship is good and it appears the Sãrki tradition may transform and survive. Rural Sãrki leatherworking is more traditional than in the District Center. All rural leather workers still have their patrons, or bistã, who pay in husked grain, money, cloth, or any reasonable request. Besides artisan duties, rural Sãrki families farm corn, millet, rice and wheat. Rural Sãrki families all do parimã with each other and specifically do not exchange labor with other castes, not even their Kãmi neighbors. Like other low castes, Sãrki do much of 51 their work for high castes and engage in unskilled farm work. They use baure (casual labor) with high castes who call them and get paid in money and a large variety of foods except cooked foods and pure dairy products (Tape 4A, #1, 1990). Unlike Sãrkis who are extremely poor and malnourished, goldsmiths in Jãjarkot make a visible profit. They earn more money than most artisans, and even more than many high castes. Goldsmith women regularly branch out into livestock herding and small shopkeeping. Especially important politically, District Center goldsmiths faithfully patronized the Jãjarkoti royalty. Jãjarkoti elite rewarded Sunãr fealty with land and access to peon government jobs. Sunãr men and women expanded into weaving, water tank maintenance, small shopkeeping, and peon government work. When their land or work was challenged by ambitious high castes, royal Thãkuri members defended the Sunãr. Low castes in the Bazaar mostly stay out commercial shopkeeping though they may be affiliated with one shopkeeper, such as in the case of the visiting leather worker above. Some tailors will lay out their sewing machines on the ãgan or front courtyard of shops which specialize in selling cloth. In this way, a customer can buy the cloth from the (usually Newãr) shopkeeper and immediately be measured for costume by the tailor. Most of these arrangements have sprung up for the benefit of government workers who arrive in the District Center with no previous paternal arrangements. Of all the artisan households, the tailor seems to fit the image best of a low caste specialist. Kaldar Damãi's family is an example of a successful low caste tailor family in the District Center. His family takes cash in addition to khalo grain payments for their services. Kaldar's wife and most of the family also sew. Their family serves 25 families of all castes using khalo. Kaldar 's brothers are the only Damãis who sew in two small satellite villages of the District Center. Some of his family members travel to Bardia District during monsoon and in November/December. They bought a sewing machine in Nepalganj in 1980 but before that they had their father’s machine, the first in the District. Kaldar’s father sewed for the king of 52 Jãjarkot in A.D.1931-32. family owns no land but their earnings from khalo and piece work are more than sufficient to cover their cost of living. The fact that they own no land is a symbolic marker of their perennial service to landed elites. The following is a breakdown of Kaldar ’s piece rate. Besides receiving khalo from patrons, their household also receives about Rs. 60-100/day for piecework. The rates are fairly standard for all tailors in the Bazaar as of 1990. ( Rs. 28 = $1.00) Table 5.2 Standard Tailoring Prices in Jãjarkot Bazaar Prices for Tailoring Item Men's Women's Shirt Coat suruwãl (pant suit) ïoro (string pants) Cholo (blouse) Maxi (dress) Rupees 20-25 150 40 40 8 15-20 In Bardia prices are about 20% higher according to Kaldar. His time is rather elastic in that Kaldar can work in Jãjarkot or Bardia, either out of his home or at the home of his patron since his sewing machine is portable, and he estimates that he earns roughly equal amounts of money and grain. Some customers are also low caste; for Sunãr families Kaldar does piece work which he calls jãla, which is technically bartering tailoring for goldsmithery. For Kãmi families he similarly barters his work for their ironsmithing. If Kaldar or one of his family members went to work for landlords as an unskilled laborer, they would surely not make as much as for their tailoring. Compared to daily wage labor which in Jãjarkot pays about Rs. 25/day, Kaldar's work earns him a good hourly wage. Kaldar only took about 1.5 hours to sew a maxi dress I requested. Daily, Kaldar said he earns about Rs 60/day. In general quality of life of the District Center artisan is better than for rural artisans. District Center artisans earn a cash wage, have plenty of customers (bistã), and even sell liquor and pork to augment income, which high castes normally abhor selling. 53 The other ubiquitous low caste thar in Jãjarkot is the Kãmi who are known for their ironsmithing. Despite competition with ready-mades, Kãmi ironsmiths continue to make a variety of tools. Every agriculturist has to call the Kãmi to fix the tips of hoes, make kitchen knives, sharpen axes, and make animal bits. Even I called the Kãmi to make my kitchen knife (chulesi) since I forgot to bring one. I called on Gohilye Kãmi, an ironsmith who worked mainly in the District Center. His wife, Setu, was one of the major firewood providers for District Center elite families. Unlike many artisans, Setu and Gohilye owned enough land to produce half a year's supply of wheat and corn. They have little time to farm since they're busy with selling firewood, alcohol, doing casual labor for elite neighbors, and ironsmithing. They hired a sharecropper even though their field is only half an hour's walk away. They do join with relatives to do parimã exchange labor during rice transplanting and they regularly use sahayog to help neighbors, such as hauling slate roof tiles up to the District Center. One of Setu's pleasures is to make alcohol for her extended family during festivals. At Rs. 10/bottle, she also earns more money than many neighbors. Below is a list of the products her husband regularly makes as an ironsmith. Table 5.3 Products of Kãmi Ironsmiths in Jãjarkot 1. ãsi (hãsiya) 2. syãki 3. bancãro 4. khukuri 5. chulesi 6. bãso(bãrselo in Hofer 1973) 7. kuëo 8. kodãlo 9. kodãli 10. katãri 11. karïwa 12. chakku 13. chhurã 14. chhino 15. sãgãlo, puli sickle knife of one hãt length (@12”), straight and sharpened on one side axe saber, made famous by Gurkha soldiers kitchen knife, food is pushed through the knife while person kneels on its platform wood shaver or adze used by carpenters, short shaft, broad blade garden hoe, short handle, fairly long thin blade hoe with small thick blade like a shovel (masculine) hoe used to transplant rice, millet (feminine) twin bladed knife saber sheath (and small knife in sheath) small knife small saber wood punch used by carpenters to make holes chains, especially for doors 54 16. tãlca 17. (name)? door padlock bit to harness oxen while threshing Ironsmiths build their own kilns, mine some of their own iron and coal in Jãjarkot, and travel about in a one to three day migration route. They can build either permanent kilns or small temporary fires for fixing broken tools. Often they will have their sons with them who watch and help with small chores like collecting coal and watching the fire. Actually less than half of Kãmi households still do ironsmithing. It is possible that even in past centuries, Kãmi households did most of the unskilled farm work. Kãmi women especially make up much of the agricultural labor force in Jãjarkot. They collect khalo payments, visit their bistã (patron) for grain payments, beg for casual labor, and bring firewood from the nearby forests and sell to their bistã. In general Kãmi families do much of the unskilled labor in Jãjarkot. Within the District there exist a broad number of service occupations, yet only a few service castes reside in any one village. A Gãine, for example, travels through an arduous 3-day service area, playing the violin-like sarãÿgi and singing songs. Most service specialists have large ranges of clients, including the priest, astrologer, ironsmith, coppersmith, goldsmith, potter, prostitute, and some leather workers. Service specialists today compete with non-specialists and goods portered in from the south. Indian made clothing, iron, cheap metal goods, and plastic pots are one sign of the introduction of ready-made goods. These directly compete with ironsmiths, goldsmiths, coppersmiths, potters, and tailors. Ready-made cigarettes compete with the clay pipes of Bãdi women and men. Radio music competes more than ever with traditional Gãine and Bãdi singers. The HMG Forestry service banned some of the woods used by Sãrki leather workers and they cannot make flour sifters (chalnu). Their services have also been overwhelmed by introduced rubber shoes. There is still a small market for knife sheaths which the Sãrki carve out of wood. Rawot ferrymen transported people across the Bheri river in kisti, hollowed out 55 wooden boats, charging them a handful (mana) of flour or whatever they could barter with their passengers. If a boat was not available there were, and still are, hollowed gourds (ëumba) which the ferryman fastens around the passenger’s waist in order to float the nervous patron across the swift Bheri River. But today three suspension bridges span the Bheri River along a path of nine hours' walking distance. Ferrymen are still available, but less often in demand. Low caste artisans have no equity with the living standards of high castes in the District Center. The list of lower standards is long. Most low castes live in a run-down neighborhood with bad footpaths, no electricity, and broken water taps. The area is dirty and smells of garbage and dung. Houses are similar to high castes’ but smaller, simpler, without extra amenities like two or three stovetops (chulo), beds (kãt), several water pots (gãgro), or well plastered walls (lipeko bhittã). Children play with pigs as pets, while high castes favor rabbits as pets (though both are cute). Male artisans without enough bistã migrate to India during the winter, looking for wage work. High castes discriminate against low castes with verbal abuse when low castes start to act or look like high castes. Low caste women were outlawed from wearing saris until only a generation ago. They still prefer to wear blouses, waist wraps, and skirts rather than saris. Some low caste parents discourage, even prohibit, their children from attending school. Starting a shop or tea stall is difficult, and even impossible without patronage, since high castes would harass them and not frequent their business. The District Center artisans’ landholdings are even smaller than artisan castes in the rural countryside. From all this disparity, still there are low castes which manage to create cohesive and proud networks of family members. In order to see the differences in the lifestyles of artisans, low castes in general, and high castes, I now turn to a quantitative depictions of labor relations. I continue to focus on the roles of khalo and jajmani, and how these contribute to the expression of patronage. The Division of labor According to the Rules of Social Caste 56 High and low castes have distinct divisions of labor. From simple observation, one notices that high castes pursue education, government office jobs, care of their yards and gardens of fruit and vegetables. Low castes, broadly, appear more engaged in household cleaning, plastering, building and construction, artisanship, and menial chores. In the rural villages, low castes appear to work in high caste fields or sit around the yard taking care of children. In order to quantify my impressions, I took an activity survey of about 30 households which I called the Labor Relations Survey (LRS). See Appendix D4 for data collection parameters and activity subcategories (85 subcategories). For the LRS I collected quantitative data on work activities only for one month using the Status of Women reports as a survey template (Acharya and Bennett 1981). An activity survey was not one of my research goals in the beginning of my work. However, I decided that it would be helpful to see quantitatively what activities householders did, at least during the spring planting months. A statistically significant survey should take all twelve months into consideration. I therefore use the LRS as merely a guide to seeing how different categories of householders spent their time in 1990. With 505 recorded observations I can make a few observations regarding division of labor by caste. First, low castes are doing a variety of work besides artisanship. Low caste women especially are overwhelmingly involved in doing housework, often for high caste households. Since low caste households have less land and livestock, they look for daily labor to provide subsistence. High castes, on the other hand, prefer farming and livestock production. My Labor Relations Survey (LRS) using Caste as one dimension of the division of labor, depicts the following pattern: 57 Figure 5.6 Tabulation of the Division of Labor by Caste Strata #observations/total #observations (505) recorded April/May 1990 Use Word 6.0c or later to view Macintosh picture. *Data collected from households non randomly selected in the District Center , a village satellite, and two rural villages with as broad a range of socioeconomic circumstances and caste representation as possible. Five households were also headed by females. High castes more often engage in earning income, animal herding and agriculture than low caste members. When they do hunting, it is often for sport to hunt pheasant and boar. When they do plant gathering, it is often for flavorful liuro greens or to gather religious leaves for a ceremony. Food processing was not an important activity in April/May but will become important in the fall after corn and wheat are harvested. Low castes most often do housework and manufacturing activities. Low caste women are regularly employed by high caste women to plaster, grind grain, clean dishes, carry wood 58 and water, and watch children. Artisan work is depicted in the ‘manufacturing’ activity which includes the subcategories ‘making cloth , baskets, mats, ropes, repairing utensils, leather work, sewing, metalworking, or related manufacturing’ (see appendix). Cash income earning activities make up less than 8% of total activities in Jãjarkot yet are important to total contribution of family incomes, especially for high castes.ii Both caste strata took similar amounts of time for personal activities (education, personal toiletry, attend social activities, visit, rest, play, sit, dance, sing, play music, other personal) although their specific choices differed. High castes were often in school or with a tutor while low castes did not pursue education. Both castes took similar time away from family (migrancy was infrequent in April-May due to planting season). Yet the reasons for traveling out of the District differed between high and low castes. High castes most often reported that a family member had gone to visit her maiti (parents) or relatives. Low castes sometimes visited relatives but often were still in India as migrants even though the migrant season was over. Division of labor is probably most affected by one material condition - the amount of land a family owns. I turn now to examining the landholding sizes of various castes. From this information one can see landholding sizes of not only artisan castes but of high castes as well. High and Low Caste Differences in Land ownership I looked at variations in land ownership by caste and geographical region. Overall, I found that high castes own substantially more land than low castes, which is common knowledge. Uncommonly known, however, are the following points: 1. Land parcels have the largest discrepancy between high and low castes in urban areas (District Center) and least discrepancy in rural areas. 2. High castes do not have enormously disproportionate amounts of land compared to low castes except in the District Center. 3. Landless low castes who do not do artisan work have limited choices of work. 59 4. Despite frequently earning a good income, artisans can not accumulate land easily. 5. Landholding size greatly influences labor decisions and labor relations. I now turn to the evidence for the above findings. Conditions in rural areas are quite different than in the District Center along several axis. Rural villages are marked by more access to forests, grazing pastures, marginal and uncleared lands, local medicinals, wild plants and animals, and people more easily partake in local politics. District Center and peripheral villages, on the other hand, have more access to government jobs, government office services, imported goods and food (especially rice), electricity, higher education, a Bazaar and tea stalls, and political and district - wide meetings. Since there are significant geographical variations, I gathered socioeconomic data from three regions, categorizing them into the Rural Region Survey (RRS), Peripheral Region Survey (PRS), and District Center Survey (DCS). The Rural Region is located over one day’s walk away from the District Center. The Peripheral Region is located up to half a day’s walk away from the District Center. The District Center is delimited by the central three political wards in Khalaÿgã. See the Appendix for information on survey parameters, questions, and general results. Indigenous labor practices in Jãjarkot vary geographically because labor is related to land ownership. People in rural areas farm their own land but in the District Center and peripheral regions, large landowners hire mohi, tenants. In rural areas, artisans own more land than District Center artisans and have less patrons. Householders peripheral to the District Center serve the District Center clientele yet still own their own land and farm subsistence crops. They provide dairy, fish, labor, grain, even forest greens to the households on the hilltop of Khalaÿgã. Dairy farmers in peripheral villages, for example, supply District Center tea stalls and wealthy families with milk and yogurt. In rural areas, villagers do not provide the District 60 Center with goods and services. They consume much of their own dairy and make tins of ghiu (clarified butter) for occasional sale to Jumla, Dolpã, or Nepalganj. Below I present information on land ownership in Jãjarkot stratified by geographical region: 1) the District Center, including 40 households of long-term residents; 2) the peripheral region, including households outside the District Center which are up to four hours' walk away (N=118); and 3) the rural region, including 118 households located over four hour's walk from the District Center. Table 5.4 Jãjarkot District Center: A Comparison of Caste to Land Holdings h.h. = household; pop. = population; Caste N= h.h. % of pop. Land % of Holding Land/ (ropani) caste Bãhun Thãkuri Chhetri Newãr Damãi Kãmi Sunãr Wãr Total 1 11 14 6 5 1 1 1 40 2.50 27.50 35.00 15.00 12.50 2.50 2.50 2.50 100.00 12.0 458.0 553.0 259.0 20.0 3.0 11.0 0.00 1316*~ High Caste Low Caste Total 32 8 40 80.00 20.00 100.00 1282.0 34.0 1316.0 Ave. Land Holding/caste (ropani) 0.91 34.8 42.02 19.68 1.52 0.23 0.84 0.00 100.00 97.42 2.58 100.00 32.90 12.00 41.63 39.50 43.17 5.00 3.00 11.00 0.00 32.90 40.06 4.25 *Six answers given in Muri units only. Converted through an average of 2.4 Muri per Ropani on Khet and Pãkho lands combined using only grain production. 2.4 Muri average based on surveys which provided information on both land holding size and grain production yields. ~Of the total Ropani, 630 Ropani [48.5 Bigha] are owned by high castes in the terai lowlands, not in Jãjarkot District. Thãkuri, Chhetri, and Newãr castes have significantly higher average amounts of land per household than other castes.iii Part of the reason lies in their ownership of land in the terai 61 (Nepal's southern lowlands). As absentee landowners, high castes do not farm their own land and instead leave it to tenants (mohi). Since District Center high castes engage in many types of work besides agricultural labor - teaching, accounting, shopkeeping, and government contracting - many high castes, and a few busy artisans, make tenancy arrangements. Land ownership by caste from Peripheral Region Survey (PRS) includes households from about twenty villages up to four hours' walk away from the District Center. Table 5.5 Comparison of Caste and Land Holdings in Peripheral Region of Jãjarkot h.h. = household; Pop. = population; Rop. = ropani Caste Bãhun Thãkuri Chhetri Magar Damãi Kãmi Sunãr War Gain Bãdi Unknown Total N= h.h. 11 40 36 8 4 10 3 1 2 1 2 118 Hi/Lo Caste: High Castes 87 Low Castes 29 Unknown caste 2 1.68 Total 118 % of Pop. Land /caste (Rop.) % of land/ caste 9.24 106 8.03 33.64 493 37.35 30.24 516 39.09 6.70 56 4.24 3.36 26 1.97 8.40 76 5.76 2.52 18 1.40 0.84 8 0.60 1.68 3 0.20 0.84 4 0.30 1.68 14 1.10 99.14 1320 100.04 11.19 73.12 24.34 14 99.14 1171 135 1.06 1320 88.87 10.23 7.00 100.06 Ave land holding/ caste (Rop.) 9.64 12.32 14.33 7.00 6.50 7.60 6.00 8.00 1.50 4.00 7.00 13.46 4.66 11.19 Notes to table: a. Information collected from households in 23 villages up to four hours' walk from Jãjarkot Bazaar. See PRS in Appendix for information on survey parameters. b. Jaisi/Joisi Bãhuns fall under the Bãhun heading. I didn't record any Giris or other Jogi castes in the Peripheral survey but place them in their own high caste category in other surveys. Magars listed with high castes in compiled data. 62 c. Two surveys refused to give a caste name and are recorded as "unknown". d. 1 hectare = approx. 20 Ropani. e. N = "number of households". "% of Pop" = percentage of household population. Total population in survey is 875 persons. "Land" = total cultivable irrigated, unirrigated, and garden land parcels of all households in each caste denomination. "% of land" = percentage of cultivable land owned by each caste denomination. "Ave land holding" = average land holding per caste household in each category. Villages peripheral to the District Center are characterized by an average land holding of 11.19 Ropani (.56 Ha.). If this average is contingent on caste, there is a significant split between high and low castes. High castes own an average of 13.46 Ropani (.67 Ha.) while low castes have only 4.66 Ropani (.23 Ha.) of cultivable land. Thãkuri and Chhetri households are dominant landowners with an average of 12.32 and 14.33 Ropani/household respectively. Gãine families own little (1.5 Ropani) and generally perform their caste duty in the paternal system of khalo in which men and sometimes children move about a 3 days’ walk territory as musicians and singers while Gãine women labor in high castes’ homes and fields. With an average household size of 7.4, families are substantially larger than in Khalaÿgã Bazaar (5.5 persons/household) In Rural areas, or those which are located about a day’s walk or more from the Bazaar, the trends of high caste control and ownership of land continue. In rural areas people often measure land amounts by how much grain they harvest, measured by muris, which equal about 160 pounds. When I would ask, 'How much land do you have?' a common answer might be, 'das - bãra muri ko dhãn, holã', or "Maybe ten or twelve muri of rice". The interviewee gave information which other Nepalese would need to estimate a household's harvest which is more important than land holding size considering there can be good grades and bad grades of land. In these cases we counted how much of each product the household harvested and added the 63 major cropsiv together for a total of muris on both irrigated and unirrigated land. We did not include garden cropsv in total muris of harvest. Below I present caste breakdowns of land holdings using both muri and ropani as measurements according to which measurement the interviewee favored. For clarity, I present land holdings only by High and Low caste frequencies. Table 5.6 Rural Villages' Frequency of Caste to Land Holdings Caste High Low Total N= 32 25 High 40 Low 9 Total 106 % Land % of of Pop. Holding/ Land/ Holding/ Caste Caste [Ropani] [Ropani] 382.15 72.55 11.94 144.60 27.45 5.78 526.75 100.00 67.92 32.08 100.00 [Muri] [Muri] [Muri] 1508.10 90.57 37.70 156.95 9.43 17.44 1665.05 100.00 Ave. Land Caste [Ropani] 9.24 33.98 *20 Ropani = approx. 1 Hectare; 1 Muri = approx. 160 pounds. *Sample survey consists of 10% of households in six villages in northern and western Jãjarkot. I recorded information from 10% of households in a seventh village but did not compile information from it for this table. Village sizes ranged from 80 to 230 households. Generally, land parcels in rural areas are slightly smaller than in peripheral areas (rural: 9.2 rop. vs. peripheral: 11.2 rop). Land holdings are slightly more equal between high and low castes since rural low castes have on average more land than their counterparts in peripheral areas to the District Center (rural: 5.78; peripheral: 4.66). In terms of muri of grain produced, the overall average of 34 muri is generous if family size is not more than 7-8 adults. But low caste families, if they have 7 persons would need about 25 muri of grain per year (2 mana [pounds] grain/person/day X about 5.5 adult consumption units/household X 365 days/year = 4015 mana or 25 muri grain/ year)vi. Even if total low caste household consumption is less than 64 25 muri of grain per year, they still need more than the current average of 17 muri (2720 pounds) of grain per year. Also, the 1989 harvests were good. In less favorable years, harvests should be smaller and this longer span of harvest time should be considered but is not part of the present information. In rural areas food must be bartered or purchased from neighbors during shortages. Buying quintals of rice from the bazaar is seldom done because the rice is low quality, hard to transport, and relatively expensive. Families with grain shortages take grain loans, do casual labor, sharecropping, give gifts of labor, migrate seasonally, or do craft specialties to augment their grain supplies. Sharecropping is a limited option in rural areas since land parcels of high castes are generally smaller, high caste families are larger, and other labor forms are available (casual labor, reciprocal labor, gifts of labor). In addition, there is no business to pursue for sons and daughters of elite landowners. Rural children tend to continue farming as their main occupation rather than become government workers, teachers, and lawyers. The trends which I highlighted earlier now seem clear given detailed landholding information. Land parcels have the largest discrepancy between high and low castes in urban areas (District Center) and least in rural areas. District Center high castes own the most land (40.06 rop.) and high caste holding sizes decrease as they live farther from the District Center. As low caste households move away from the District Center, their landholdings become larger, though not immensely so (District Center low caste 4.25 rop: rural low caste 5.78 rop.). If larger landholdings indicate greater power, then District Center high castes wield more power than other categories of landholders. The social class "landlords" defined as households who own more than 20 ropani (1 hectare) comes largely from the District Center. High castes do not have enormously disproportionate amounts of land compared to low castes except in the District Center. District Center Thãkuri households constitute 27.5% of the 65 population and control 35% of the land; in the District Center overall, high castes make up 80% of population and control 97.42% of nearby lands. In the peripheral region, high castes constitute 73% of population and control 89% of landholdings. In rural regions, high castes make up 68% of the sample population, control 73% of the reported land and 91% of reported harvests. Low caste rural households, 32% of the sample population, own 27% of land and control only 9% of reported harvests.vii This greater difference in reported harvests is alarming. There is a serious food shortage for low caste households, even given the fact that much of their grain incomes come from selling their labor. Landless low castes who do not do artisan work have limited choices of work. Many low caste households have historically been agricultural laborers, not artisans. The low caste rural household has a comparatively large landholding because these households rely heavily on subsistence farming rather than khalo. Yet slightly greater amounts of land are not enough to meet subsistence needs. Most low caste non-artisans also rely on migrancy and casual labor (baure). One rural Sãrki family, for example, makes khukuri knife covers, leather and jute shoes (from puwa :Ilex doniana), khap wooden knife holders, and leather based flour sifters (chalnu). They porter local cloth and medicinals, trek long distance across the Karnali River bridge, make and sell tetwa clothviii , and do migrant labor in Uttar Pradesh. They have “insufficient” land and regularly do baure (casual labor) for high castes, taking jhãï, rãksi, (liquors), and ready-made cloth as recompense. For rural leather workers in Jãjarkot this wide variety of jobs is not unusual. Despite this range of unskilled work, the Sãrki and other low castes have few meaningful work options. There are no low caste lawyers, medium or high ranked government workers, salaried employees, contractors, medical assistants or doctors. No low castes have successfully competed in business ventures such as shopkeeping, tea stall or hotel ownership. A few Goldsmith caste women have successfully become entrepreneurs in lending, 66 shopkeeping, and livestock production. But overall, the range of good paying and meaningful work is severely limited for low castes. Despite earning a good income, artisans can not accumulate land easily. Historically, artisan families produced for the nobility and some received land grants (birta) by Jãjarkoti kings. Today, however, a combination of land grabs, siltation from the Bheri river, indebtedness, and simple sale to high castes leaves low castes with little land. Successful artisans receive khalo from their bistã patrons and subsist with very small land holdings. Landlessness is generally seen as a much more precarious lifestyle than the small landowner’s, given the economic and political fluctuations in Nepal. Landholding size greatly influences labor decisions and labor relations. In general, marginal, medium, and large landowners have three different labor strategies available to them. Marginal households (those without enough land for subsistence) in the District Center and peripheral regions can turn to sharecropping (adhiyå). Such households can find a landed patron from the District Center who owns more land than they wish to farm. Marginal households in rural regions, however, do not have this option. These households do a wide range of unskilled labors such as portering, occasional labor to the state, migrancy, casual farm labor, and part time artisanal work. Marginal households in rural regions patronize richer neighbors, but they don’t rely on the adhiyå system of sharecropping. Medium size landowners partake of a wide range of indigenous labor relations. These families have the means to exchange labor in both cooperative and exploitative ways. They can do simple exchange (parimã), call marginal workers (baure), and give gifts of labor to their needy relatives (sahayog). Medium size families do not usually have tenants, bonded laborers, or servants. Large landowners tend to use sharecroppers and bonded laborers. They tend to pursue capitalist salaried work as teachers, accountants, government office work, and contracting. 67 The Table below gives a general breakdown of labor by high and low caste based on the 1987 Peripheral Region Survey. Each category of owner or worker (patron, artisan, etc.) will be explained in the following section. Table 5.7 Percentage of Caste by Labor Category Category Patron Artisan* Landlord Tenant Employer Laborer High Caste N=98 Low caste N=22 0.97 0.02 0.12 0.07 0.63 0.05 0.86 0.73 0.09 0.23 0.14 0.55 *'Artisan' means the household receives khalo grain payments for their services. This does not include the Bãhun families which receive sida. See appendix for PRS questions pertaining to labor categories. The Web of Indigenous Labor Practices Jajmani is definitely part of a greater network of indigenous labor relations. Seen quantitatively, then, families who rely on jajmani, for example, will also rely on certain other indigenous labor practices. One way to see if labor categories are related is to look at a correlation table. The correlation tables below are based on comparison of seven categories. 1. caste - high or low strata (coded as 1 or 0 respectively) 2. patron - bistã: any household that gives khalo 3. artisan - any caste that takes khalo 4. landlord - any household which lets land (adhiyå) 5. tenant - any household which sharecrops (adhiyå) 6. wage laborer - any household member who works for in-kind/cash (baure, jãla, haliyã) 7. employer - any household which hires extra labor (baure, jãla, haliyã) 68 If a household has members who give khalo, they are coded “1” for being a patron. If the household does not give khalo, they are coded “0”. Similarly, any caste that takes khalo is coded “1” as an artisan. Any household that rents land in adhiyå arrangements is coded “1” as a landlord. These categories are not mutually exclusive. A household may give khalo, let land in sharecrop, and simultaneously hire extra labor, for example. There is very little overlap, however, between naturally mutually exclusive categories, such as “landlord” and “tenant.” 69 Figure 5.7 Comparison of Caste, Patronage (jajmani & khalo), Tenancy, and Daily Laboring Use Word 6. 0c or later to view Macintosh picture. hi/lo Patron artisan landlord tenant laborer employer hi/lo 1.000 0.355 -0.705 0.040 -0.200 -0.548 0.453 Patron artisan landlord tenant laborer 1.000 -0.411 -0.093 0.096 -0.156 0.107 1.000 -0.007 0.093 0.364 -0.301 1.000 -0.121 -0.075 0.138 1.000 0.342 -0.184 1.000 -0.282 Significant correlations include: Employers tend to be high castes (.453) Patrons tend to be high castes (.355) Landlords tend to be employers (.138) Low castes are laborers (-.548) Low castes are tenants (-.200) Laborers are tenants (.342) Laborers are artisans (.364) High castes are not artisans (-.705) High castes are not tenants (-.200) High castes are not laborers (-.548) Artisans are not employers (-.301) Laborers are not patrons (-.156) Artisans are not patrons (-.411) This kind of information is extremely important and has been overlooked in research on jajmani. It implies that jajmani is bound into a social matrix of labor and there isn’t a way to 70 easily extract khalo and jajmani out of a productive system unless there are concomitant changes in tenancy and labor forms. A family can desist from using the khalo system, but they are still bound in all probability into partaking in other labor relations which patrons use. Such a family will not take up artisanship, will not take up unskilled laboring, and will hire laborers for many of their daily household chores. It would seem odd, actually, for such a family to break from traditional use of khalo and jajmani ties. Each of these relationships entails use of a named indigenous work strategy. Employers and laborers use baure and jãla. Landlords and tenants use adhiyå. Patrons and service specialists use jajmani and khalo. Since one category of Worker or Owner tends to correlate with another Worker/Owner category, so the same goes for labor practices. People who tend to use baure and jãla tend to use adhiyå and tend to use jajmani and khalo. The quantitative correlations have heuristic value in that they allow us to understand to what extent each of these labor practices is bound up with other labor practices. If patronage is compatible with indigenous labor practices and not compatible with wage labor, cash cropping, urban places, and businesses, then perhaps it is not too compatible with capitalism. The question becomes, “How exactly is patronage related to capitalism?” Although I cannot answer this interesting question in detail, I present information on one facet of the paternal-capitalist interface - loans and lending behavior. Below I give a detailed example of the interaction of patronage with indigenous and introduced loan systems in Jãjarkot below. By “indigenous loan” I mean a lending practice which has been used in Jãjarkot for several generations and which is known to everyone living in the region. By “introduced loan” I am referring to Nepal Limited Bank loans, Agricultural Development Bank loans, and any development monies which are lent to smallholders by NGO’s and government agencies. I specifically asked households from the Peripheral Region Survey about seven types of indigenous loans and loans from two banks. For clarification, below are presented the names and general rules for the indigenous loan forms common in Jãjarkot. 71 Table 5.8 Principle Types Of Indigenous Loans (riÿ) In Jãjarkot Name Sapati Collateral None Interest None Description Small cash loan granted to a friend; a small debt Bandhãki Home, Land, Animals, Gold None Cash loan granted in exchange for collateral which can be used by the lender while principle is on loan. Paisa Byãj (or, byãj sahit ko rin) None or same as in Bhandaki 15-30% Loan borrowed from moneylender. By law lender cannot collect interest in excess of total amount of principle but often does and reclaims collateral. Anãj None 1/3 Grain loan repaid after harvest. Given to those whose stores are depleted before harvest is complete. Udãro None None Credit at stores/shops. Usually granted on personal recognition and payments one/month. Kabul Item of value 10-20% Money/land exchanged/ pawned for an value item. If money not repaid, item is confiscated and the person becomes an indentured servant for a specified period of time, usually 1-2 years. This form may possibly lead to kamãiyã, bonded labor. Before turning to an examination of the relationship between lending behavior and social position within Jãjarkoti society, I would like to point out a couple of underlying theoretical points. Loans: The Link between the Production Forms of Paternalism and Capitalism Creditors in Jãjarkot are mainly landlords, patrons, and employers. I venture that they occupy social positions in both capitalist and paternal economic systems. Creditors attempt to create multiple social ties with their debtors. They act as landlords, patrons, and employers using 72 khalo, adhiyå, baure, and other indigenous labor relations. As part of this multiple productive network, it would not be in the patron’s best interests to sever his/her ties of jajmani with artisans. In the section below I argue that Creditors tend to take capitalist bank credit and channel this into indigenous loans to others, mainly Workers (artisans, laborers, and tenants). The relationship, {capital: patronage :: Owner: Worker :: Creditor: Debtor} is part of the complexity of labor relations, part of the 'multiple ties that bind', as L. Caplan describes it (1972). Determining capitalist and paternal debt forms When identifying a form of production (capitalism or paternalism) using the criteria of labor type, one can use several characteristics, these being the mobility of the labor, the form of debt bondage, the general labor surplus/deficit, and the forms of surveillance over tenants. By 'mobility of labor' I refer to the ability of a tenant to move from the property. If tenant is under obligation, coercion, force, to remain tied to property, the form of production takes a paternal character. If tenant can leave without undue contractual obligation, the form is rather capitalist in nature. By 'debt bondage' is meant the tenant's material obligations to the landlord directly, or to an elite class, which does not allow the tenant to break ties to the property and landlord. If tenant cannot release herself easily from indebtedness, she cannot be released from conditions of tenancy and the system is one of paternalism. Types of debt vary from cash loans, shop credit, and indentured servitude to bank loans.ix If debt bondage is absent from tenant's considerations concerning remaining/leaving the property, the system is capitalist in nature. 'Labor surplus/deficit' generally refers to whether there are more or less potential laborers per workable property. If there are fewer workers per property, the landlord uses 73 sanctions to retain tenants and the system is ideally one of paternalism. If a pool of excess labor exists, this is generally a characteristic of capitalist sharecropping. 'Surveillance over tenants' exists in paternal systems whereas other mechanisms keep control of a labor pool in capitalist sharecropping systems [competition, few resources/laborer, work ethic, tenant's investment via rent, etc.]. There are capitalist and paternal aspects to each of the above criteria in Jãjarkot. For example, 'labor is mobile' to the extent that during the winter season many near landless workers migrate to India. In the winter labor is mobile, a characteristic of capitalist production styles. Yet in the summer season, labor demands are at a premium and paternal forms of labor recruitment predominate. Debt practices originally appeared capitalist in nature because laborers appeared to be relatively free of credit obligations to the owners of the means of production. But this was true only in a direct sense of credit obligation. Tenants appeared to be free of obligation of debt payment to their landlords since there was no overt sign of debt to shops owned by landlords or of tenants working as servants without remuneration due to debt situations. But indirect debt bondage appears to be at work in Jãjarkot. And in areas south of Jãjarkot, areas in which Jãjarkoti landlords own land and maintain workers, direct bonded labor (kamãiyã) has been documented (INSEC 1992). I venture that in Jãjarkot, there is an indirect form of debt bondage at work among tenants, laborers, and artisans. I’ll refer often to these people as “Workers” since their labor correlates (q.v.: artisans tend to be low castes (-.705) and laborers (-.548) and tenants (.342)). Artisans are in a similar situation to tenants and laborers except that they own their means of production in the form of tools. Using the Pearson Product Moment Correlation in Tables 5.9 and 5.10 below, it appears that Workers are tied to traditional loan systems in patronage as an economic system. It appears that Workers are more likely to go into debt, to use credit, and to use material objects, land, and 74 their own persons or labor as collateral for credit. Below I present Pearson Product Moment correlations of categories of Debtors and Creditors. I have highlighted correlations which clearly show a relationship between the categories of Owner/Worker and the types of creditor or debtor. Table 5.9 Types of Credit Received (Debtor) Category of Debtor hi caste patron employer landlord lo caste artisan laborer tenant Type of Credit Received Indentured Collateral Service loan .062 -.277 .037 -.179 -.007 -.145 -.047 .020 -.062 .277 .128 .265 .134 .280 .174 .126 Shop Credit -.047 -.008 .163 -.030 .047 .099 .134 .195 Category of Interest Small interest ADB Debtor bearing loan free loan hi caste -.044 .040 .113 patron .007 .081 -.110 employer .091 .119 .149 landlord .106 .107 .096 lo caste .044 -.040 -.113 artisan .044 -.071 -.078 laborer .002 -.054 -.131 tenant .079 -.017 -.086 Pearson Product Moment Correlation; N=118, reject Ho at alpha .0071 Grain Loan -.081 .012 .107 -.059 .081 -.018 .208 .210 NBL .176 -.022 .378 .153 -.176 -.145 -.198 -.092 75 Table 5.10 Types of Credit Extended (Creditors) Category of Creditor hi caste patron employer landlord lo caste artisan laborer tenant Indentured Service .065 -.029 .226 .266 -.065 -.042 -.036 -.101 Collateral loan Grain Loan .031 -.088 .241 .261 -.031 -.043 .027 -.103 .091 .100 .196 .074 -.091 -.042 .025 -.138 Category of Interest bearing Small cash (no ADB or Creditor loan NBL) hi caste .049 .087 patron .002 .172 employer .193 .417 landlord .053 .279 lo caste -.049 -.087 artisan -.003 -.159 laborer -.104 .003 tenant .020 -.164 Pearson Product Moment Correlation; N=118, reject Ho at alpha .0071 Debt types - indentured servitude, collateral loans, shop credit, and grain loans One needs to look at what type of debt the Workers are accruing in order to understand the paternal to capitalist continuum of relations of production. From Table 5.9 on loans received we see that Workers concentrate their credit opportunities in several indigenous loan types. First, indentured service loans are a significant way to borrow money for Workers [.123, .134, .174]. People with no other forms of collateral choose this loan form. This category of debtor doesn’t have the credit or collateral to borrow from banks. ‘Owners’ (employers, landlords, bistã patrons) do not have any strong correlation concerning indentured service loans, indicating that a few high caste families may use kabul but generally they do not, especially if they are landlords (-.047). 76 Second, Workers and low castes take cash loans requiring home, jewelry, land as collateral [.277, .265, .280, .126]. Bandhãki loans are frequent, though I sometimes recorded a person saying that he had given/taken a bandhãki loan but had given/taken no deposit (dhiëo). Strictly speaking, this would have been a simple loan (sãpati) but occasionally people defined a loan form differently than myself. Also, various items of value can be ‘hocked’; copper water jugs (gãgro) were mentioned several times by families with little other collateral. Bandhãki loans were avoided by most ‘owner’ categories(-.277, -.179, -.145, .020) and this is probably because ‘owner’ categories are unwilling to risk a situation where they may have their possessions taken away. A much safer risk would be low interest loans from the banks at 1220% interest rates or interest free loans from friends. ‘Owner’ categories did, in fact, tend to be the people who give Bandhãki loans [.241, .261]. In areas around the District Center where land use is at a premium, high castes probably seek out people who are willing to surrender the use rights to their land in exchange for cash loans. Credit from shops usually based in the Bazaar represents a third frequent form of indigenous loan which laborers [.208] and tenants [.210] and also employers [.107] use. Shop credit in Jãjarkot is unusually stable and there is no interest charged on the monthly debt. The large shops in the District Center always had medicines, cloth, shoes, dry goods, and paper supplies. Their prices are of course higher than in the terai, with mark-ups of 33%-100% and this partially accounts for interest free credit. There is no reason why anyone with a good repayment history should not take shop credit and in fact most shops had hundreds of accounts where their customers were required to repay monthly outstanding debts. Shops in rural areas were the only ones which often didn’t use a credit system. Owners complained that they knew all their customers and couldn’t refuse them credit; but the customers were very slow to repay and shopkeepers either had to shut down their shops or they reportedly didn’t make any profit at all. 77 Grain loans are probably the most expensive type of debt, requiring 33% interest repayment only months after taking a loan. If a family is destitute just before a harvest, for example, they may borrow 20 units of grain from a neighbor (about 1 months’ supply of rice) but they must repay 30 units of grain after their next harvest. This is the kind of loan patrons [.100] and employers [.196] tend to give. Since landlords generally don’t participate in fieldwork, they probably won’t give grain loans but cash loans more often. Laborers [.208] and tenants [.210] frequently use grain loans to tide their families over before harvests. Money lenders, simple loans, and banks The category ‘interest bearing loans’ is the frequently stereotyped ‘usurious moneylender’ mentioned in ethnographies about South Asia. In Jãjarkot few people borrow from the moneylender. Landlords (.106) and employers (.091) are the only categories which tend to take these loans bearing a 30% per annum interest rate. Tenants [.079], too, may be using high interest loans but the reason is not clear; possibly to maintain subsistence, or possibly as a venture into meeting high labor costs at harvest time. While not represented in the survey, I do know that Bãhuns tended to be common moneylenders, especially Bãhuns working for well organized private moneylenders in the terai. These non-residents of Jãjarkot are not part of this survey. In this survey only employers [.193] tended to give moneylender styles of loans. Employers, opening shops or trying new trading ventures, are most likely to give and get quick but high interest credit. Small no interest loans generally consist of amounts up to a thousand Rupees and they are used by Owners, mostly among close friends and family. Several times I borrowed money to pay for unexpected costs and it was no problem because my research assistant or friends in Jãjarkot trusted that I would repay them. Likewise, I often saw high castes lend money without writing a contract or making a lot of stipulations about repayment. The categories Employer [.119 debtor; .226 creditor] and Landlord [.107 debtor; .266 creditor] tended to use sãpati most 78 frequently. Surprisingly many families denied using sãpat(i). For example, when a village contractor (employer category) forgot to go to the bank and get money to pay his workers (laborer category), he asked all his high caste friends and relatives. No one would give him money. Surprised, I asked him, ‘Have you ever given anyone else sãpati before?’ expecting that he could go to people he had lent money previously. But he said "No, I've never given anyone sãpati." Perhaps this is because they didn’t want to 'beg' money or grain from friends (being “riÿi ” or beggarly). As a word of caution, peoples’ responses to questions about loans (riÿ) are ideal. Some people said that they never take any loans and neither does anyone in their family, which is unlikely. However, most Workers said they neither give nor take small loans. I tend to think that they probably give very small loans on occasion but they assumed I meant loans such as Rs. 300-500 without interest which most Workers probably do not lend. I often saw Workers asking, or begging (mãgnu), for money or food but not usually asking for a small loan. Again, for Workers it would probably be most beneficial to seek collateral loans, or to “hock” their personal items in exchange for some land to plow or money to buy cloth. Finally, looking at bank loans, we see that the ADB (Agricultural Development Bank) and the NBL (Nepal Bank Limited) are used primarily by high castes. Findings: 1. Workers and low castes in general tend not to be involved in the Agricultural Development Bank [ADB] or the Nepal Bank Limited [NBL]. Low castes [-.113 for ADB; -.176 for NBL]; Tenants [-.086 for ADB; -.092 for NBL]; Laborers [-.131, -.198] and Artisans [-.078, -.145] probably don't seek out credit from government sources. One reason may be that a bank loan means interest repayment of 15-22%. This requires full entrance into a wage earning economic position yet few Workers do wage labor full time in Jãjarkot. Another plausible reason for the paucity of loans given to Workers is that bank lenders favor high castes, persons with high status in the community, and persons who clearly have ability to repay loans. 79 Government credit for use in agricultural production means entrance into a distinctly capitalist form of production. The loan must be repaid, the request must be for production which will produce a cash flow, and approved projects are those which generate an income. Such projects as fruit farming, vegetable farming on a commercial basis, increased livestock production with the intent to sell dairy products, and weaving training, marketing, or loom building are a few of the reasons loans are extended by the Agricultural Development Bank. Another factor mitigating Workers' entrance into a cash for credit economic system is the banks' reliance on written communication. I don't have a correlation using education level in the PRS statistical group but I know that Workers have extremely low education levels. One of the parallels of participating in ADB/NBL credit systems is the need to read/write vouchers, credit slips, deposit and withdrawal statements, etc. Another plausible factor for a negative correlation between workers and use of government credit systems relates to a time factor. It takes a 'long' time to conduct a transaction, 1- 2 hours being not uncommon to deposit/withdrawal funds. For those living 1-4 hours from the Bazaar, transportation time adds more delay in performing cash transactions.x 2. Owners are positively correlated in relation to the credit system and especially employers [+.149 for ADB, +.378 for NBL]. Employers are closely linked to a cash economy in Jãjarkot. Employers earn a cash income for part of their total income. They sometimes pay workers in cash (though usually in grain). The NBL is used mostly as a source of deposit of cash and gold rather than as a source for loans. This would explain why high castes [+.113] use the NBL as well as employers. The bistã Patron correlates negatively [-.110], probably because many people are Patrons, not just materially wealthy people but small farmers with little cash but who need the services of the ironsmiths and tailors, etc.. Overall, it is logical for people who have already started to accumulate capital to continue to do so via banks. Such people in Jãjarkot include government workers, salaried workers, shopkeepers and anyone whose production yields cash surplus. In Jãjarkot, since only 80 ten hectares are devoted to cash cropping (ADO interview, 1990), farmers are not participating in banking yet. Farmers are more likely to have surplus in grain, livestock, or movable property. The question I posed at the beginning of this section was, 'Are Workers bonded to Owners?' This can now easily be resolved. Workers are bonded to owners indirectly through traditional credit forms. When workers begin to take credit from government sources, the debt bondage so characteristic of paternal systems will be severed and replaced by debt in a capitalist system through the extension of cash credit and repayment schemes founded on simple commodity agricultural production [fruit and vegetable cash cropping, weaving projects, surplus rice, etc.]. A few Owners in Jãjarkot have made this transition and rely on government credit rather than traditional loan forms. Loan behaviors in review Owners (patrons, employers, landlords) tend to supply indigenous credit to Workers (artisans, laborers, tenants). Owners use repayments, and interest to reproduce their own social needs, increasingly capital intensive needs. For example, just as I was leaving Jãjarkot a wealthy family in the District Center was planning to purchase a television, which would be the first in Jãjarkot. This family owns a well managed store and participates in both indigenous loan giving/receiving and uses bank credit. Owners’ strongly want to advance themselves, and practice conspicuous capitalist consumption even though no television stations broadcast into Jãjarkot. Their ideal goal is to become modern, a notion fraught with connotations of capitalist ideology. The modern District Center household strives to leave the work of their fields to baure day laborers, and adhiyå sharecroppers. Workers do not have the extra money to afford luxuries such as a television. Few people in the peripheral region can live a life of consumption and leisure. In rural areas, very few people consider leisure and conspicuous consumption even a worthy ideal. Contrasting 81 with District Center ideals of conspicuous consumption, is a strong rural Nepalese work ethic. In rural areas agricultural activity is valued. A person relaxing might be scolded, “kasto alchhi” (how lazy!). A hard worker is one who finds more things to do when she finishes her job. A sojo mãnchhe, “straight person” is also highly respected and trusted; they are honest, good workers. Several times female heads of households chided me for just listening to a tape recorder and writing in my books. Instead they suggested that I be out in the fields helping the other women. Rural women during the day take little time off for leisure activities. Workers also must fulfill their social needs but sometimes they don't have enough grain to eat or clothing to wear. Since their surplus is generally appropriated by Owners, social reproduction for workers is tenuous. They need cash, grain, and land when they slip below the line of subsistence. Indigenous credit both creates and maintains minimal subsistence. Workers participate in indigenous lending because they have difficulty getting government credit. For example, Chamre Damãi‘s family in a rural village did get some credit from the government. They built their home with a loan of Rs. 8000 on 1.5 ropani land with the help of a low interest bank loan (7%). They wished to expand into raising and selling buffalo (Worth at birth: Rs.500, at young adult: Rs. 1500) but the ADB refused them a loan, saying they should organize a group of 9-10 families with similar goals in order to get a loan. Other low caste families would like to be part of the buffalo raising venture, but the ADB won’t come out to the village and help organize. They say loan officers came once and gave some people a loan for raising and selling chiuri oil but they haven’t themselves managed to get a loan. Credit officers (all high castes) often don’t purposefully discriminate against Worker categories and Artisans such as Chamre Damãi’s, but the petitioner’s poor living conditions, inability to front collateral, and illiterateness mitigate their chances of a fair hearing for government credit. Finally, indigenous loans continue to be overwhelmingly popular in the face of government credit because Owners “bind” Workers to them in a form of paternalism. Lionel 82 Caplan addresses the question of how lenders and borrowers reinforce their ties and feels that 'To appreciate the implications of credit dealings, we ask what each partner is attempting to gain, what the transaction is all about, and how it relates to other transactions involving the same persons.' (1972:700). In short, creditors in Jãjarkot create multiple social ties with their lending partners. They’re inclined to act as employers, patrons, and landlords in a system of multiple social ties which reinforce other indigenous labor systems, including jajmani , khalo , and adhiyå . Conclusions It isn’t just that high castes are ritually more “pure” and therefore they come to dominate other social strata as patrons. An explanation for social stratification based on ideology or moral reasoning would be incomplete. High castes and "Owners" dominate other lower strata through control of material resources both presently and historically. Their labor exchanges use adhiyå, khalo, baure to create asymmetrical relations with Workers. Owners not only have more land but also more educational and political resources to claim additional land and wealth. The real question becomes, "What mechanisms do high castes employ to maintain their control of material and ideological resources?" Domination and patronage is made easier through the use of various indigenous labor practices like loans and khalo. Patronage enjoins low caste artisans to continue borrowing loans which ensure the continued domination by elites. Institutionalized begging allows high castes to gift small donations to low castes and ideologically bind low castes to the gifters. Patrons argue that artisans have no need for land, a prime material resource, because they get their grain through khalo. Political and educational issues are the domain of patrons, they argue, because artisans have no need for involvement in issues primarily concerning land and lending. An educated person in Jãjarkot has historically been one who can write legal documents. Patrons argue that artisans and low castes in general 83 without much land need not write legal documents, need not concern themselves with politics, and should rely on their bistã patrons for help in land and money conflicts. In studying patronage, especially jajmani and khalo, I realized that the role of loans needs more emphasis in discussion of jajmani. I probably would not have noticed this pattern of lending and debting and connected it with jajmani relations if I had not examined the relationship of labor categories and lending behavior. Using a sample of 120 surveys, one can see that Owners have used indigenous loan systems to supply themselves with accrued interest and land. Low castes and Workers, on the other hand, have used indigenous loan systems to maintain subsistence where they have little material wealth, especially land, to meet their household subsistence needs. Loans become a means of creating “multiple ties” to patrons. As Lionel Caplan wrote: “Each of these instances [landlord - tenant, lender - borrower, religious preceptor - disciple] is not unlike the Nepalese situation where a creditor not only may offer his debtors loans and tenancies and employment as agricultural laborers but will mediate their disputes, give advice and assistance on a variety of problems, and in general attempt to increase his hold on the debtor and so constrain his freedom of action.” (1972: 702) A system of paternalism, using khalo and loans, is separate but related to capitalist systems of wage labor and banking credit. It would be wrong to imply that paternalism creates or motivates capitalism, since capitalism creates free trade and unrestricted movement in market situations which Jãjarkoti households are just encountering. But it is equally incorrect to assert that capitalism created paternalism since paternalism finds its historical roots in the sovereignty of Jãjarkoti nobility. Overall, my goal in this Chapter has been to show that paternalism and capitalism in Jãjarkot are linked yet have distinct variations. N otes to Chapter Five 84 iSince Gharti means 'ex-slave' many names can precede this family name. Thapa Gharti was one common name in northern Jãjarkoë. ii I collected the LRS data in the ‘off-season’ for migrancy, which is March - November. Since I recorded observable work activities and reported work activities, such as “Ram went to herd goats”, non-observable work, such as migrancy and portering, are in reality contributions to households’ income but not reported here. iii For this land holdings information I didn't interview men or women who where temporarily employed by the Government and who came to Jãjarkoë less than four years' ago. This effectively excluded those workers who had been sent to Jãjarkoë as government employees because these people normally had land and families in other parts of Nepal. iv Major crops include rice, wheat, corn, barley, millets. v Garden crops can be fairly varied. Usually garden crops are for household consumption, not sale. See appendix for a list of garden crops common in Jãjarkoë. vi For my consumption calculations I used information from J. Metz, 1989a. Patricia Caplan (1972) and Lionel Caplan (1975:249) write that villagers eat 2 mana/day and "Bazaariyas" eat 1.3 mana/day, based on 'edible grain' which is husked grain. They also calculate 480 mana = 60 pathi = 3 muri per healthy over 14 yr old adult given the categories 10-14 yrs eat eat .5 units, 3-9 yrs eat .25 units, under 3 = 0 units. Thus a household is measured by age and then grain consumption is counted. For example, a family of five may have a consumption unit of 3.75. In Jãjarkoë, I calculated average consumption size of households for five rural villages. In one village of about 20 surveys, for example, the average household's consumption size was only 3.9. This was one of the poorest villages in the survey. 3.9 x 2 units grain [mana] x 365 days = [2847 mana = 355.88 pathi =] 17.79 muri/year. Families in this village should produce at least 17.8 muri grain each year for standard a Nepalese diet. Village 1 2 3 4 5 vii Average Consumption Size/ Household 3.9 4.8 7.3 4.3 5.1 Estimated grain needed/ year [muri/year] 17.79 21.90 33.31 19.62 23.27 Interview schedules were determined by counting the number of castes and households in a village and selecting nonrandomly a ten percent sample for interviews. For example, given there are 100 households, comprised of 10 Brahmin families, 20 Chhetri families, 20 thakuri families, 10 Magar families, 10 Gosain families, 20 Kami families, and 10 Damai families. The interview sample ideally consists of the following representatives: 1 Brahmin, 2 Chhetris, 2 Thakuris, 1 Magar, 1 Gosain, 2 Kamis and 1 Damai. The ratio of high to low castes in this village would equal 7:3. I then request my village representatives to introduce me to one- 85 third "rich" households, one-third "medium" households, and one-third "poor" households. viii ix The weaving of tetwa was a dying practice though it may be reestablished in a newer form of production. They hadn't made cloth in a couple years and their children probably were not going to learn tetwa weaving. There are other types of indigenous lending practices in other parts of Nepal, such as dhikur in Gurung communities and paisa utaune circles in Muslim communities in the terai. I did not hear about these types of indigenous credit associations in Jãjarkoë. Messerschmidt 1972; 1978 writes about a form of rotating credit system called dhikur among Gurung in central Nepal which does not apply here. Dhikur aren’t used in Jãjarkoë. In Nepalganj in the terai, closer to Jãjarkoë, the closest indigenous style of group debting is simply called paisa utaune , to “raise money”. It is usually done for funerals and weddings by both Muslims and Hindus and is probably an adaptation to poverty in capital intensive socioeconomic surroundings. For more information on rotating credit in S. Asia, see Also Kurtz, D. 1973; Anderson, R. 1966; Hanley, M. 1989; Geertz, 1962; Ardener, S. 1964 x I don't want to subtlely disparage the government credit system. A 2-hour bank transaction can have value to the transactor in ways other than time spent for no productive end. The transactor will meet influential people while waiting at the bank and may conduct alot of politically and socially important business, including finding out about political elections, government development contracts and work in the area, local political meetings, marriages of one family faction to another, land for sale, a supply of seed available, etc. 1 6 THE WORKER'S WORLD: TENANCY, DAILY LABOR, AND CASUAL LABOR ...property is a relation, not a thing, to be analyzed as a relation between persons with respect to things. Marilyn Strathern The Gender of the Gift Every highly stratified society has historical ties to the institutions and practices of slavery, compulsory labor, tenancy, daily labor, unskilled labor, agricultural labor, and migrancy. In this chapter I trace the exigencies of sharecropping (adhiyå), daily labor (jãla), and casual labor (baure), three common labor practices in Jãjarkoë, in order to understand cultural perspectives of workers. The perspectives of illiterate, common, and generally poor householders lies largely outside the hegemonic cultural views of elites. Using this subaltern perspective, I examine the logic of productive social relations between workers and other householders in Jãjarkoë. As a working definition, I define "workers" as people who labor on projects which they themselves do not own or control. All people may "work" yet a worker is defined by her or his relationship with the contractor of worki. As might be expected, indigenous labor practices are often "exploitative," in that unequal exchange of value (symbolic, political, economic, cultural, or other) consistently occurs between the labor giver and labor receiver. Yet the hegemonic ideals of patronage and milaune (to get along with others) obscures Nepãli 2 asymmetrical social relations. My view, that relations between workers and patron/nonworker/owners are negotiated yet ultimately asymmetrical, is surprisingly contrary to Messerschmidt, 1981 and other researchers of indigenous labor relations who largely see indigenous labor in a romanticized fashion (Ardener 1964; Geertz 1962; Kurtz 1973; Martin 1986; Worsley 1971). Because indigenous work forms are non-capitalist, researchers sometimes assume that labor practices are egalitarian or superior to wage labor in capitalism. The world of workers has been neglected in South Asian literature because of a focus on jajmãni ties of patronage. Throughout this dissertation I have maintained that jajmãni is one small part in a larger system of productive social relations. In this chapter I argue that sharecropping (adhiyå), free labor (jãla), casual labor (baure), are also part of productive social relations. Previous researchers were fascinated by jajmãni as non-western and exotic while universal yet culturally variant labor forms such as free labor, casual labor, sharecropping were overlooked. I have organized this chapter into three sections. The first section, called "Rule-Bending: Worker Interpretations of Elite Rules," investigates more than just "everyday forms of resistance" (J. Scott 1985). I maintain that tenants, laborers, and low castes in general break social rules because they cannot adhere to the elite rules inherent in idealized Hindu models. Workers' normally cannot afford to follow appropriate behavior set by elite edicts, especially rules of behavior for marriage. I've chosen information about marriage and worker rule - bending because I have diverse interviewed information on marriages. I offer the examples of several Hindu marriage proscriptions and how these are often broken by workers. In Part Two I present information from socioeconomic surveys on differences among worker - households and those which do not work for others, which I call "non-workers." I have found not only that workers lead lower qualities of life than non-workers, but I offer documentation of differential socioeconomic conditions. Workers, for example, avoid 3 participation in formal politics, seldom visit development offices, rely on agriculture and livestock work rather than salaried employment, perform more domestic work than other households, and their families have higher mortality rates and vastly less education. Even though workers perform more work, they earn less money and have lower quality diets than other households. My goal is to go beyond mere generalizations that workers are exploited; I wish to examine the culture of those who are exploited. In Section Three I conclude by discussing the variations in meaning of sharecropping, daily labor, and casual labor. For elucidation I excerpt interviews in which workers explain their definitions of sharecropping, daily labor, and casual labor. This section is important because the details of sharecropping and casual labor have yet to be discussed in the literature on Nepal. Introduction to the Worker's World It may be unsurprising that workers are exploited. In western and capital intensive societies, exploitation of wage workers is a given. Yet society in Jãjarkoë does not run on wage labor. Western observers, when faced with non-monetary labor relations in Nepal, sometimes unconsciously assume indigenous labor relations are more egalitarian, more utopian, and more naturalized than workers' realities from their own societies (i.e., Brower 1990; Exo 1990; Metz 1990; Zurick 1990). For example, Metz admirably details livestock production patterns in Myagdi District, another middle hills region of western Nepal. He notes that "villagers fertilize their fields...herders take the livestock into the forest...a family member accompanies the animals...the livestock are moved frequently in a complicated pattern... and villagers practice conservation measures." (1990:8). While indigenous livestock production methods need to be written about, it is also important to explicate the social organization of the indigenous labor. Metz' s study details nothing about which households or the members of each family who actually do the livestock work. In a caste hierarchy, most work devolves to lower castes and 4 women. In order to understand the role of indigenous "conservation measures" we have to start acknowledging that much of the actual work is founded upon unequal relations of production. Until recently, researchers have had little appreciation for the lifestyles of the people, the workers, who actually carry out most indigenous labor. This chapter is entitled The Workers' World because their world seems so different, exotic, and even sensational to me. No matter how many interviews I conducted, photographs I examined, and times I participated in unskilled labor tasks, I still find myself unable to bridge the divide between my own world and theirs. It is nearly impossible to imagine being illiterate, first of all. All workers are illiterate and therefore both men and women see objects differently than I. They enthusiastically march up to trees and talk all about them, they tell stories of river ghosts, they sit in the wheat fields weaving wheat stalks into butterfly-shaped ornaments for home decoration. Their literacy is in reading the tangible and supernatural objects around them. I also can not imagine thinking of the geographical world with a rural hilly epicenter. All workers have a sense of geography limited by what they have heard. For example, I stood next to a Jãjarkoëi woman as we replanted rice stalks and she asked me, "Do your parents come from near here?" We laughed so hard when someone told her my parents lived very far away. But it was her polite way of telling me I looked different even though she did not want to be blunt and intimate that I looked foreign. She certainly had never seen a person from so far away, had never talked about news from distant places. Some workers do have a reputation for traveling, the migrants. These people even get nicknames of the furthest places they've worked. One man was nicknamed 'Ladakh' because of his adventures so far from home. Each migrant comes home with many fabulous stories from their travels. My milk delivery boy, Kanchha, expressed his wish to accompany me as a porter on walkabouts. When I took him traveling, Kanchha was shocked. In western Jãjarkoë he remarked, "This is like another country!" yet he had not left his own District. When we went to 5 Dang District he got on a bus for the first time and would not sleep for two days straight. He laughed and tried to share his wonder of a moving vehicle with others around him. In Kathmandu, he declared he was much more excited about buying a wrist watch than seeing the doctor. I can not imagine most workers' worlds, their excitement for the things I take for granted. Their points of view are important, if only because there are so many workers, yet the worker's world is little represented in literature. Mostly we write from the literate and elite person's point of view, not because we are elitist, but because it feels natural and literacy is valued in a society which focuses on education and upward mobility. In India much bonded labor (haliyã) has transformed with the Green Revolution into wage earning free labor. One might presume that wage labor in Jãjarkoë, like India, is the primary system of paying agricultural laborers, and that capitalism is the driving force behind it all. While cash wages account for some cement in binding labor relationships, Jãjarkoëi households also rely on gifts of labor, reciprocal labor, grain in exchange for work, and sharecropping agreements in the negotiation of agricultural labor. I maintain that non-capitalist forces, especially patronage, dominate agricultural production in Jãjarkoë. By looking at the worlds of workers, I demonstrate that the hierarchy of caste has created a pool of workers for a dominant high caste segment of society. In Jãjarkoë land constitutes a major resource; control of land and agricultural production is a key component of status, wealth, and work. The crux of the low caste “problem” revolves around land ownership: most low castes have insufficient land to support themselves. While skilled low castes perform artisanal skilled work, unskilled low castes turn to seasonal migrant labor, sharecropping, daily labor, or bonded labor to meet subsistence. Near-landless workers will continue to labor for others unless they either get more land (improbable) or move into a stable industry (also improbable). 6 In Jãjarkoë no stable industries operate except paper making, weaving, bee keeping, furniture building and a couple other tiny workshops. Even these are wavering projects; the District Capital's paper workshop has been closed since 1990. Low castes may turn to high caste sponsored illicit activities, mainly trading in cannabis, musk, prostitution, and making homemade liquor. Yet most Jãjarkoëis who participate in informal economies and migration say they will never permanently work in the informal economy or become a sukumbãsi (itinerant wanderer/migrant) even if employment is scarce. Interviews with Nepalese migrants in Uttar Pradesh confirmed this; only one man in our sample of Nepali migrants had taken up permanent practice in Nainatal, renting his horse for rides to children. We need to understand how nearlandless workers, both women and men, survive if their agricultural options are sporadic, they eschew permanent migrancy, and there are few opportunities for industry and wage labor in general. I discussed social classes theoretically in Chapter Three, concluding that in Jãjarkoë classes greatly depend upon land ownership and labor practice. To review, the classes which theoretically exist in Jãjarkoë include 1) landowners, 2) owners-with-tenants, 3) ownercultivators, 4) laborer-cultivators, and 5) landless laborers. The social category (not class) of "worker" draws from the landless laborer and laborer-cultivator social classes. With the idea of "workers" as people who work for others, usually do not own their own means of production, and live at subsistence level of social reproduction, I now turn to an ethnographic understanding of workers' social circumstances. Rule Bending: Worker Interpretations of Elite Rules In the middle of the District Center lies the neighborhood of low caste artisans. They live a visibly lower standard than the neighborhoods around them, much as a slum neighborhood in cities. There are few workable water taps, no electricity, no paved walkways, and no outhouses. 7 High castes visit in order to buy homemade liquor (rãksi), pork, and have tailoring and goldsmithing done. One sunny afternoon I sat on a stained wool rug, playing with children, swishing flies, and tape recording interviews. As a goat passed water on the rug, we stood up, and an old woman, Setu, set down a load of firewood. I asked the war [carpenter] caste woman about the firewood tax. She brings loads of firewood nearly everyday to the District Center, lugs twenty kilos of earthy damp branches from woods in the distance that she measures by whether she can see the forest or not. When asked if she pays the yearly tax of fifty rupees to the forestry department she said, "that is 50 rupees from my stomach." The firewood carrier would never have paid a fuelwood tax, as the Forestry Office decreed, unless there was a way for her to earn above subsistence for the work. Workers can not and do not live by the rules of high castes. This is not an excuse, but reality. The written and unwritten rules of high castes systematically favor elites. When I saw workers abandon legal and socially defined rules (niyam, kãnun, chalan) I initially wondered if they were bad people, inherently inferior, or just stupid. But after collecting examples of how low castes act, how they fare during confrontations, and how they are subordinated, I realized that rule bending is more than just "everyday forms of resistance.'"(Scott 1985). The people who have never made the rules simply have different ones; one cannot pay taxes if s/he can not feed themselves in the first place. One might add that landowners, elites, and administrators de facto do not live by their own rules either. The District Forestry Officers and other high ranking salaried forestry officials do in fact accept illegal monies from special interest groups and individuals. In another District, for example, I noticed an individual pay a lumber tax for wood which was of inferior quality when in fact he lumbered another type of higher quality wood. He paid the forestry officer for the "bait and switch." This tattle would be indiscreet if not for the fact that it is common knowledge that bribery and informal payments are terrible problems in Nepal. When the woman 8 tells of refusing to pay a simple Rs. 50 tax, it seems almost trite in light of huge paybacks by elites. Marriage Proscriptions and Rule Bending Some of the most common rule-bending behaviors involve marriage rules. By Hindu decree, households should be patrilocal, marriages should be arranged, a woman should bring a dowry into her husband's family,ii and a woman should remain devoted to only one husband in her lifetime because her salvation is dependent upon such aspiration (Chakravarti 1990:33). Nonetheless, most of these proscriptions are rendered by workers. In the District Capital several low caste men lived with their wives' families, a matrilocal residence. When a family is near destitute, they may choose matrilocal residence if the wife's family has more resources. The same rule bending applies to marriage wealth. When a man is poor he cannot easily marry a woman with dowry. In Jãjarkoë a poor man will move in with the new wife's family and work for them (brideservice). The pattern of brideservice is actually quite common among Magar, Gurung, and Tamang ethnic groups, even when Hinduised. Men from outside the district occasionally marry local women, giving brideservice and using matrilocal residence. These outside marriages have been disastrous in some cases however. A particularly poignant case was that of a Bãhun girl, "Devi." She married an Indian man who had come to teach in the local school system. While their family was of the highest caste, still they had no land, and the father, a Jogi ascetic, was ailing and frail. All the agricultural and domestic duties fell to the teenage daughter. After Devi married the Indian schoolteacher it became known that he already had a wife in India, but by that time it was too late. Devi became pregnant and a boy child was born. Still she could not hold her husband. He left, sneaking out of the village the very day of his son's feeding ceremony (bhãt khãne pujã).iii 9 Devi now works for others but the villagers euphemistically call her labor sahayog [gifts of labor] rather than the more realistic epithet, baure or jãla [casual labor]. They give her enough grain for her small family and people find little tasks and make excuses to invite her for a day of work. She will be planting on an absentee landlord's land next spring without paying him and the landlord only smiles and wishes her good planting. He knows she is destitute. This is partially because the Bãhun - landlord family social ties are strong; a generation ago the landlord greatly influenced and patronized Devi's father. Social alliances involving marriage are critical for high castes, patrons, and landlords because they imply the negotiation of power. From the perspective of workers, however, marriages are less about power because so little actual influence exists among low castes and near-landless families. Instead, marriage represents more of a bargaining into extended families who have developed safe vertical ties of fealty; such worker households cope well with the exigencies of tenancy, begging, and maintaining safe ties to local mukhiyãs, patrons, and landlords. Another Hindu ideal which workers often disregard is the prohibition against remarriage of women. Countless times I interviewed worker household wives who were on their second and third husbands. One old woman had married seven times. Jãri, a little-documented practice, is common here. I have read about it only referred to as a "kind of social system which exploits women" (INSEC 1992). Yet of the descriptions given me in Jãjarkoë, it seems that jãri has a liberating effect for women. When a woman leaves her husband and goes to another, the second husband used to be obligated to fight the first husband, even to the death. This ideal is arcane, however, and was told to me in stories of jãri conflicts from "long ago." Today, men pay former husbands thousands of rupees rather than fight.iv The emphasis on jãri may stem from cultural interactions of Khasa immigrants into Jãjarkoë with local Magar communities. Magars practice remarriage and the Khasa, although they were historically Hindu, did not follow many caste rules (Joshi 1929). 10 In one example of jãri, a 21 year old man, T.J. Pun, returned to northern Jãjarkoë in April after five months of migrancy. My group met T.J. on the path leading to their village, his group and mine walked together, laughing and playing in the streams, looking at the prayer scarves previous travelers left upon the trees and rocks in which gods and ghosts dwelled. When I stopped by his house the next day, I got the news that his wife has deserted him. Coincidentally, I met this same group of migrants, about six men, when they were in Nainatal, Uttar Pradesh. My research assistant and I interviewed them as part of my 1989 Christmas "Vacation," where we traveled around Uttar Pradesh meeting Nepalese migrants. T.J.'s party of six planted their November wheat at home and set off for Chinchhu, a town in far western Nepal to trade for salt. T.J. had married Premila, a love marriage, the previous summer. T.J. and his friends had never labored as migrants but they abruptly decided to walk, bus, and train all the way to Nainatal. They hooked up with a met, a Nepalese labor organizer in U.P. who found them work. Even though they earned about Rs. 40/day, they complained that it was not worth it to migrate, especially when T.J. found his wife had left him in his absence for another man. The jãri he would get had not been determined. We guessed maybe Rs. 1000 for his loss and grief. The incidence of jãri and divorce is high in worker households and women with migrant husbands cannot realistically obey Hindu marriage strictures because of both emotional and practical necessities. I am not sure why researchers insist on using stereotypical rules for Hindu people. Marriage rules are some of the most stereotyped in the literatures I've read (i.e., Bennett, 1983; Chatterjee 1972; Fruzzetti 1975 Henry 1975; Inden and Nichols 1977; Wadley 1977). Researchers either describe ideals or use idyllic styles of wedding preparations as their ethnographic examples of marriages, days of preparations, songs that have to be sung, and feasts that have to be prepared. From these idealized literatures we imagine every household negotiating dowries and bickering over gift exchanges. Low caste and class women's marriages 11 and love marriages are often marginalized into the research specifically about untouchables (see Moffat 1979; Mahar 1972). The practice of defining arranged marriages as the standard marriage practice marks love marriages and simple marriages as unusual. Yet most of the low caste worker women that I interviewed had love marriages. Are love marriages "everyday forms of resistance"? My informants never said they were. They usually said they could not afford an arranged marriage; these marriages then were not an ideological "resistance" but a practical impossibility. From examples I've recorded, it appears that love marriages have some variations, not simply that two people love each other and choose to marry. For example, the period of knowing the marriage partner is usually brief, just as with arranged marriages. As Sita, who had no education stated, she met her husband when they smoked a cigarette together... They agreed to marry, had a small wedding and received one bullock from Sita's parents. Other times the marriage partner is a lover. An immunization worker from a nearby district fell in love with the local women's development coordinator. They flirted and met for several months before one night sleeping together. Afterward, they announced their wedding and even got a certificate from the District Office to document their marriage. Another common theme in love marriages is to attend a fair (melã), meet a sensual man with a good reputation, flirt with him, and allow him to take the woman home, or yet more scandalous to the Hindu high caste stereotype, allow him to become a lover. Many love marriages among workers begins with the recognized coresidence and small pujã (ceremony) of two lovers. The headman of a rural village had a reputation for meeting women at fairs. The Mukhiya ("headman", his nickname) liked to tell tall tales and told me one about his wifely abilities: 12 Mukhiya: Well, my father could go to the fair and to big meetings. I wasn't permitted to go to the fair because if I did go, I might bring back a wife and start a huge quarrel here! Therefore my father, fearing a disturbance, made me stay at home. Friend: The Mukhiya used to bring a wife back from every fair when he was young! Jana: How many wives did your father have? Mukhiya: My father had two wives. We are from the first. He had Kãnchi [younger wife] also. And if father could bring back two wives so we should bring back as many wives as there are hairs on a head. So if I went anywhere I brought back a wife. Jana: After a short time did they go back home? Mukhiya: They had to go home. New wives came and old wives left the house. When one became old I brought back a new wife. The Headman's cavalier attitude about wives was, in context, really only part of drinking, joking, and gossip. In reality, his elder wife was very sick and the Headman was very worried about her and expressed this in other contexts. Other marriages, such as that of an entertainer caste man named Dipe Badi', typifies the experience of courting for a mate at a monthly fair. Dipe is born of the Entertainer caste which today includes a variety of duties. Badi workers may be dancers, prostitutes, musicians, fishermen, net weavers, pipe makers and most practice a combination of duties. Dipe met his 13 wife in a melã (fair), during Mage Sukrãnti (first of the month of Mãg holy time). He and his future wife danced and did pujã (religious worship) together and they then decided to marry. They had a traditional Badi wedding. The bride's family sponsored the feast, and then they went to Dipe's house which he had built with help of a War [carpenter] caste family. Because worker class women sometimes marry more than once, it often happens that their first marriage is arranged and subsequent ones are not. For example, Maya Luhãr, 27 years old, was first married at 15 years of age. Her first marriage occurred in India and it was arranged. But neither she nor her husband liked each other; "it went bad," she said, and she left. The second marriage took place locally and was with a man she knew. Her own family[maiti] gave nothing for the wedding since it was a love marriage.v Many low caste artisans and workers did not follow elite rules. Marriage rules are a good example of rule bending simply because they are so proscribed by high caste elites and it is so taken for granted that everyone follows them.vi workers do not follow these caste marriage rules, even if they know about them. It is not because they feel outside of caste law, but because the marriage proscriptions are slightly absurd to their everyday conditions of existence. Arranged marriages are for people who have some reason to pick and choose partners. workers are not going to arrange partners based on wealth - everyone is surviving at subsistence level with only a bullock or two to spare for the newlyweds. Elites use arranged marriages to find economically and socially suitable links between families. Low caste, marginal, and worker families certainly care about the quality and reputations of families with which they form marriage alliances, but they have such little social status and wealth that arranging marriages would be somewhat pretentious. Love marriages are much more plausible than arranged marriages even if they do seem to break the rules made by elites. Socioeconomic Conditions Of Laborers 14 In this section I shall document how households which regularly work for other households have poorer qualities of life. This is important because we already know that the "exploited" have less opportunities than "exploiters" but each historical circumstance is unique. Thus I will first present information on 1) time use patterns for worker versus Non-worker Households; and 2) differences in socioeconomic circumstances of rural high caste from low caste households, keeping in mind that low caste status and laborer status highly correlate (.548). Second, I venture that the worker's world is one of both paternal and capitalist productive relationships. This statement is more difficult to show either quantitatively or through interviews. As I demonstrated in Chapter Five, workers are indebted to Owners indirectly through their frequent borrowing of certain indigenous loans. Laborer indebtedness to the Owner of the means of production is usually a characteristic of paternalism. Yet capitalist characteristics are also present. When workers migrate from November to April, they display mobility, a characteristic of capitalist productive relations. In the winter there is a labor surplus and most capitalist works - construction by the government, for example - occur at this time period. I discovered in this research that paternalism dominates in Jãjarkoë, however. For example, when tenants sharecrop on long term basis for a landlord, they form paternal productive bonds. In the summer during certain peak agricultural work periods labor is scarce. Labor scarcity is characteristic of paternalism. In order to give evidence that paternalism is stronger than capitalism, I give information on 1) low levels of income; 2) high levels of khalo and parimã; and 3) low participation in development office opportunities by households which work for others. Figure 6.4 Time Use Pattern for worker versus Non-worker Households for population over 12 years 15 *Measured in # observations (505) divided by total # observations per category Worker N=175 observations moments (26 households); Non-worker N=330 moments (25 households) Percentage of Activity Moments 35 30 Worker Non-Worker 25 All 20 15 10 5 Absent/unable to work Personal Income Earning Construction Housework Food Processing Manufacturing Hunting/Gathering Agriucultural Animal Shepherding 0 *Labor Relations Survey parameters and definitions of each category in Appendix. Total activities equals 100%. The image of work gleaned from one month, baishakh (April-May), shows workers as involved more in agriculture and housework. Marginally, workers are also more involved in 16 livestock herding, hunting/gathering, manufacturing, and construction. The overall depiction is one in which worker households have taken over much of the unskilled and some of the skilled labor necessary to everyday production in Jãjarkoë. Non-workers, or those households in which no family members do sharecropping, labor for others, or artisanship, are notable for the greater amount of salaried work they engage in. These families pursue occupations in tutoring, teaching, legal consulting, accounting, government office work, and monthly salaried positions such as forestry guard or hospital peon. Non-workers often engage in personal activities and are more often absent or unable to work. Broadly, Non-worker households are moving out of agriculture and into salaried work. They tend to take more leisure time, especially men. People from these households tend to travel to visit relatives and go on business trips more often than unskilled worker households. The depiction of worker and Non-worker households above is qualitatively different than capital intensive economies. In capital intensive households workers have a wide range of smaller class positions: blue collar, deskilled white collar, pink collar workers, petite bourgeois. A time-use survey of these types of workers would be much different than the depiction of worker households due to the agricultural nature of work and the small variation of work possibilities in Jãjarkoë. Jãjarkoë labor is thus different from urban, industrial, and capital intensive situations; workers do labor for others, and they come from a Laborer-cultivator and less often from another social class. Non-workers pursue their own productive achievements as independent farmers, landlords, salaried government officials, teachers, lawyers, traders, shopkeepers, accountants, priests. Yet there are small distinctions in Jãjarkoë between teachers and lawyers or priests compared to these work categories in capital intensive societies. Another way to discover quantitative differences between worker households and others is to go through information from their socioeconomic surveys. Below is a Table of Means comparing living standards by caste. I give the table comparisons by caste rather than 'worker- 17 Non-worker households' for comparative purposes with other research and because caste and labor status highly correlate. 18 Table 6.1 Comparison by Caste Strata of Data Relating to Standards of Living Subset of RRS in Western Jãjarkoë Category Caste Strata Unit of of Data High Low N= 32 N= 25 Household Size 6.53 7.88 Persons in H.H. Deaths 2.90 4.08 Under 5 years Education-Male 8.75 2.88 Total # yrs of males Measurement I. Household Education-Female 2.50 0.04 or Females in H.H. II. Agriculture Land Holding 13.84 5.57 Ropani irrigated/non Grain Production 17.31 7.89 Muri Vege/Fruit Production 13.09 7.76 Species grown Large Livestock 11.06 5.16 Adult cow, buffalo, pig goat, or sheep III. Income Grain/Livestock 2122 522 Labor 1699 5014 1989/90: Rs.28 = U.S. 1 Trade 10397 1208 Rupees per year 2740 433 Rupees per year 16958 7167 Rupees per year Gov't/Other Total Rupees per year 19 IV. Labor Practice % Ploughs 6.3% 68.0% % Employs for Plough 21.9% 0.0% % Bonded/Free Laborer 9.4% 84.0% % Employer of Labor 46.9% 0.0% % Does exchange labor 71.9% 44.0% to neighbor 56.3% 72.0% to gov't40.1% 32.0% % Does gift labor % Does Migrant labor 28.1% 52.0% The results uphold the depiction of a segregated caste society where lower strata work to maintain the standard of living of higher castes. Low castes have larger households and higher mortality rates of children. Low caste families are illiterate, the men in the households only having gone to school for a combined total of about three years; women and girls rarely go to school. Looking at Table 6.1 Sections III and IV, we see that low castes in rural western Jãjarkoë earn fully 70% of their earnings (Rs. 5014) from 'Labor' as a category.vii Comparatively, high caste households earn merely 10% of total earnings from labor. Almost all low caste households work at least part time for wealthier high castes and in fact 84% of low castes do daily labor for high castes. Low castes overwhelmingly are chosen to plow for high castes: 68% of low castes work for others in plowing compared to just 6.3% of high castes. Interestingly, about 72% of high caste households use parimã, exchange labor, compared to only 44% of low castes. Yet the reverse is true of "gift labor" (sahayog): 56% high castes gift labor help while 72% low castes donate labor. I interpret these responses about parimã and 20 sahayog to mean that high castes have sufficient land to organize themselves into reciprocal labor parties while low castes have so little land that labor reciprocity is unwarranted. However, "gift labor" is often a euphemism for a poor person offering to help work with the implicit request to be fed. In short, low castes offer to help their neighbors in exchange for food more often than high castes because low caste households frequently experience food shortages. To substantiate that low castes do sahayog less out of altruism and more out of food needs, we see that low castes much less frequently donate labor (32%) for government projects (technically called "sramadãn"). Finally, households not meeting subsistence often use migration to fulfill their needs. Most people I spoke with said migration was not a preferred choice. Yet over half of low caste households in the western Jãjarkoë survey sample chose to send a family member to India, while only 28% of high caste households made this choice. One reason low castes choose labor to meet subsistence is because they have not enough arable land. Larger low caste families rarely own enough land to meet subsistence levels. Low caste families on average only produce 7.89 muri, half or less of family grain needs.viii The ideal "dinko dwi mãnã" (2 mãnã rice/day) often is not consumed by low caste families. During the year there are periods of fasting, people get sick and eat less on a regular basis, adults get stomach and bowel disorders which require them to change their diet, food shortages dictate that non- preferred and less food is eaten, and some men consume alcohol (rãksi) and meat instead of eating regular meals. Vegetable and fruit production averages only about 8 species on the plots of low castes indicating low castes rarely get their nutrition from vegetables. Although forty types of vegetables and fruit trees commonly grow in the area, low castes find it difficult to improve food quality for several reasons. First, they have not enough land to grow more food varieties. Second, they concentrate on producing more calorie rich foods such as grains rather than elite foods such as fruits and vegetables. Third, they rarely receive seed from government sponsored 21 nurseries because of competition with higher status households. Some high castes say that giving low castes improved seed stock is just a waste of good seed. Finally, they're working on high castes' lands most of the time, so low castes do not place a high value on their own vegetable/fruit production. Livestock and dairy products are another important aspect of production and household consumption in rural areas. Low caste families own about five adult large animals such as water buffalo, goat, or cattle, while high castes have closer to eleven large livestock per household. Livestock are important for fertilizer, dairy, and plowing. One might think that near-landless households need few animals for fertilizer or plowing. On the contrary, most near landless families do the plowing for their high caste neighbors and must own two bullock. At least one nursing water buffalo is also essential for daily milk, yogurt, ghiu, etc. Cows are very good for fertilizer, most households have one, and could use more to fertilize rented land. A good indicator of whether families have enough livestock for subsistence needs is to check whether they sell livestock or by-products. Low castes' average sales in this area is only Rs. 522 (= about U.S.$ 18.64) which, compared with high caste household sales of Rs. 2122 (= $ 75.79), means that low castes normally earn little money from livestock sales. In fact, half the surveys of low caste households show they did not earn any money in this category. Of the families that did earn money from livestock and grain sales, almost all sold tins of ghiu or traded goats and chicken. We never recorded low castes selling grains. If most rural households earn only a small income, it would be one indicator that nonmonetary productive relations operate in Jãjarkoë. Average income (cash and in-kind) is about $82/year from grain and livestock, $78/yr. from labor sales, $177/yr. from Business, $69/yr. from other sources, usually government work. This totals an average of $406/yr./household or $84/yr./capita. Yet incomes vary a great deal depending on factors such as landholding size, 22 caste, historic trade and migration practices. Below I give information on total incomes from eight rural villages over four hours' walk away from the District Center. 23 Table 6.2 Income from RRS surveys in Eight Villages in Jãjarkoë h.h.= household; Rs. = Rupees; lvstock = livestock; in 1989 28 rupees = U.S. $1.00 Village Site N= Grain/ Labor Trade Other Total lvstock (h.h.) (Rs.) (Rs.) (Rs.) (Rs.) (Rs.) Hi caste 13 14075 13609 39510 55228 122422 Lo caste 11 8101 32895 1050 0 42046 Hi caste 5 17330 14560 11500 0 43390 Lo caste 4 8710 6500 33392 0 48602 Hi caste 9 18103 7590 159591 9080 194334 Lo caste 5 2960 30478 13140 0 46578 Hi caste 5 29540 17700 133600 9000 186840 Lo caste 4 1000 12655 0 0 13655 Baraban Dali Dasera Japhra 24 Lanha Hi caste 16 68984 12250 11000 57212 149446 Lo caste 2 2110 0 9125 12000 23235 Hi caste 8 21255 12000 0 0 33255 Lo caste 1 4605 1800 500 0 6905 Hi caste 11 30904 6960 92030 35595 165489 Lo caste 2 11060 0 6000 0 17060 Hi caste 5 6195 15492 0 14400 36087 Lo caste 5 1000 49328 16000 10824 77152 72 206386 100131 447231 180515 931263 34 39546 133656 79207 22824 275233 106 245932 233787 526438 203339 1206496 Pali Samaila Suwana Sum(Rs.) Hi Caste Sum(Rs.) Lo Caste Sum(Rs.) All castes 25 Total/ h.h. ($U.S.) $82 $78 $177 $69 $406 $15 $14 $32 $13 $84 Total/ person ($U.S.) 1990 Rs. 28 = about $U.S. 1 * Represents in-kind and cash earnings The above depictions of incomes points out that households must do other types of production to meet subsistence than merely produce for sale. Especially low castes, this category must participate in exchange labor and gifts of labor for food in order to survive. In Jãjarkoëi society, both patronage and capitalism are crucial production forms which enable households to meet subsistence. As noted in Chapter Five, labor is paternal if 1) labor is relatively immobile; 2) there are debts to the patron; 3) there is a general labor deficit; 4) Owners supervise or account for their laborers. Labor can be characterized as capitalist when 1) labor is mobile; 2) there are no debts to the Owners (of the means of production); 3) There is a labor surplus; and 4) There is no surveillance over laborers (other coercions retain labor). Most importantly, if there is a dissociation of the means of production from the producer, a capitalist relationship between labor and owner has begun. Theorists of capital sometimes make incorrect assumptions about the nature of capitalist or feudal relations (for example, Frank 1967). Incorrectly, the idea that a society has "exploiters and exploited" does not constitute a capitalist relation of production. This is far too inclusive; exploited and exploiters exist in every form of production. Second, Capitalism is not an 26 economic system; it is a social relationship. One can not equate capitalism with the use of capital and with market economies since these are part of non-capitalist economies as well. One must locate capitalist relations within the process of production, not the process of circulation. As Marx wrote, "The real science of modern economy [capitalism] only begins when the theoretical analysis passes from the process of circulation to the process of production..." (Capital, vol. III, p. 331). The defining relationship of capital is marked by the dissociation of labor from the means of production. A most important factor to distinguish capitalist productive relations is that laborers become dissociated from the means of production. When the worker household does not own or control her means of production, she has probably entered a relationship of capitalism. In Jãjarkoë many relationships are not capitalist. Artisans almost always own their tools of production. Sharecroppers almost always control every aspect of production. Casual workers in baure control their own labor, their own tools, but not the land on which they work. Migrants, on the other hand, work in a capitalist environment. They do not own the apple orchards, potato fields, roads, or buildings on which they work. In Jãjarkoë Government construction workers do not own the hospital, roads, or irrigation canals on which they work. Such projects are capitalist in nature. The situation in Jãjarkoë is fascinating because no simple dualism takes place. One cannot say that workers perfectly meet the criteria of feudal-paternal relations of production, nor can we say that conditions for capitalist relations are in place. In the final section below I outline the definitional qualities of sharecropping and livestock share holding in Jãjarkoë. Again, I find that while shareholder relationships are sometimes capitalist in nature, most often they are decidedly more paternal. Semantic Variations Of Sharecropping In Jãjarkoë 27 Since labor practices shift in meaning throughout Nepal, and certainly throughout South Asia, I feel it is important to write more about the ways sharecropping, free and bonded labor, and casual labor are conceived and practiced in Jãjarkoë. In this section I discuss the local meanings and methods which workers employ to organize their labor. I hold that a paternal form of sharecropping is one with the following characteristics: 1) shareholder has known landlord for a long time, a relationship stemming from the shareholder's previous generations; 2) the shareholder does not grow crops for sale as commodities; 3) the landlord does not sell his or her surplus from the sharecropper; 4) the shareholder is not informed or encouraged to raise production through developed seed, fertilizer, or training; 5) the bond between landlord and sharecropper is often strengthened through other mutual activities such as a creditor/debtor relationship or a patron-artisan relationship in the extended family of the sharecropper; 6) a system of sharing the harvest such as adhiyå is practiced rather than a contract of renting land. Sharecropping Only about 15-20% of Jãjarkoëi households participate in sharecropping. Most households have either too little land to let out, or enough family members to work their land. A few households have pursued their low caste occupations full time and let out their land holdings to relatives as sharecropping agreements. Kut, another sharecropping system, is seldom practiced in Jãjarkoë, though common knowledge of it exists. In kut the landlord contracts with the sharecropper to be paid a pre-set amount of grain regardless of the harvest's outcome. This system is characteristically more capitalist in that the sharecropper simply pays a grain or cash rent on the land. The closest practice in Jãjarkoë to simple rent of land like kut is lending money and using land as collateral (bandhãki ko riÿ). With practiced calculation, a landowner can give his land to a sharecropper who gives him a 'loan' for the use of the land. Land values can be as much as Rs.10,000/ropani ($4,000/hectare). A lender may give 60% of the value of a piece of land and 28 often asks for less than 20% interest per annum. The landowner gets a greater cash flow, does not have to farm his land, and the sharecropper gets more land to use. This is not a common practice either, however, because of potential problems with returning money, recouping land, and determining interest rates. In these cases the sharecropper/lender often wins out. The landowner often spends the money, can not repay with interest and loses his land. But such are the stakes in making land deals. Much more common is simply adhiyå, etymologically from adhe meaning "half."ix Adhiyå is a land tenure agreement between a landowner and tenant in which the tenant gives half the harvest to the landowner. In the nineteenth century landowners occasionally combined a form of land grant, birta, (tax free land grants held in perpetuity) with sharecropping. In birta the Jãjarkoë King or Nepalese state granted lands to private landholders, often Bãhuns and artisans, in exchange for political fealty, favors, and tribute. Circa A.D. 1790 Nepal allowed Jãjarkoë Rãjyãs (Kings) to keep Sarbangamafi Rãjyã status, which entitled them to enjoy birtã grants for themselves, assign birtã to others, and collect their own taxes and land revenues on these lands from tenants. This was in effect, a feudal kingship. A decade later any grants made by Jãjarkoë Rajyas were terminated except those to Gharti (ex-slaves) Magar and Chhetri caste households. This edict was not enforced however for several decades into the nineteenth century. In my interviews elite elders could not remember any cases of birta tenures being granted by the Jãjarkoë Kings. I assume that birt was much less common than free holdings (raikar)x. With the melting away of land grants, sharecroppers increasingly worked for landowners in raikar tenure (private, taxable to state). Jãjarkoë , unlike most of Nepal, had no jagir land tenures as of 1853 (Regmi 1978: 286; 338; 468)xi. Rather than jagir or birt holdings, I heard of Jãjarkoëi households giving grain and food tributes to local village functionaries, of tax collectors visiting rural folk to take tribute to the Kings, and of nobility using the services of rural common folk and low caste artisans without 29 paying fees. Thus Jãjarkoëi administrative functionaries and royal elite were paid for their services in tributes rather than birt. Subinfeudation may have been prevalent in Jãjarkoë yet it was not so much in land holdings as in political personage and appropriation of agricultural products and services. In present-day adhiyå, the tenant and landlord divide the produce, usually of rice, wheat, corn, millet and mustard, giving up to one half of the harvest to the landlord. In areas near the District Center, where most landlords live, tenants give one half the produce. In areas more than a days’ walk from landlord’s residence, tenants usually give only one fourth or one third share. When there is drought and crops fail, tenants often do not provide landlords with harvest unless coerced. The tenant supplies inputs including plow, draft animals, natural fertilizers, insecticides or chemical fertilizers (seldom), and labor, including hiring labor during peak work periods. Both landlord and tenant equally contribute seed for planting. Irrigated lowlands are popular sublets since tenants are able to subsist on wetland better than dryland. Ideally percentage of harvest yielded to the landlord should be based on the registered quality of the land. Awol, doyam, sim, chahar, pancho are the highest to lowest grades of land. An HMG cadestral survey team was just measuring the land in Jãjarkoë in 1989 and grades of land were sometimes not recorded. Most tenants negotiate with their landlords for what percentage of the harvest should be handed over. The exchange between sharecropper and landowner is an obviously political process embued with possibilities of unequal exchange. Most sharecroppers in Jãjarkoë are “informal”, meaning they are not formally registered on the Certificate of land ownership (4 Number paëwãri; there are several certificates). About 25% of low castes in the PRS indicated they were tenant households and about 10% of all castes practiced sharecropping. At the Land Tenure Office (Bhumisudhãr Bibhãg) however, the District 30 Officer admitted that only a handful (“maybe five or seven”) tenants were registered on certificates. Thus almost all tenants are unregistered. Registered tenants have several advantages over informal tenants. They are entitled to bestow sharecropped land to their families, though they cannot sell their leases. Formal, registered tenants also can get 25% of the value of their rented lands if the landowner sells the land and releases the tenants. Probably most importantly, landowner cannot evict tenants unless they've been negligent or refuse to deliver a share of the harvest.xii The Lands Act, 1964 legislated the rights of formal tenants. Unfortunately the result was a negative shift of rights between workers (bonded laborers and sharecroppers) and landlords. The relationships, often generations' old, shifted toward short term informal leases in order to minimize tenant rights (Theisenhusen 1988). For example, a Kãmi tenant, who rented land from a Thãkuri in the District Center, described how he had been the tenant formally for many years. But the Thãkuri wished to sell his land and did not want the Kãmi involved. So the Thakur sold the land to the (illiterate) Kãmi for Rs. 30,000, tore up the old certificate and said he would send the Kãmi his new deed, a process which takes several months. When the Kãmi asked for his deed, the Thãkuri denied having received Rs. 30,000 from the Kãmi and showed him a new deed without the Kãmi’s name on it. According to the former tenant, his family has essentially been swindled out of a lifetime’s savings, and he filed a Land Dispute claim which was not resolved when I left Jãjarkoë . Not all tenants are destitute; some actually manage their subsistence and are even ‘successful’. One of the more prosperous tenants I interviewed worked for several landlords. His case is significant because it demonstrates how he manages not only estates of several landowners but a crew of hired help during the year. An interview with a landlord and sharecropper 31 In the following excerpt I asked Mr. Khatri about sharecropping. I requested that he join myself and his new landlord for drinks and snacks. The meeting was unusual in that I normally did not interview a landlord and tenant together. The conversational exchanges between tenant and landlord highlighted the unequal relationship in subtle ways. Landlord: How long have you worked as a tenant? Tenant: I've been working for the last 23 years. Landlord: Whose land are you working on? Tenant: I'm working or I've gotten Adhiyå for 3-4 lands: among them one piece belongs to the wife of the Dittha [government court officer] in Pulgaun and another belongs to one Bãmni [Brãhman woman]. [In addition he worked on Landlord’s wife's father's land until landlord recently purchased it.] Researcher: In total, how much paddy do you get from doing Adhiyå? Tenant: In total, I get about 50 muri of dhan, from the land and half of that I have to submit to the owner of the land, and the other half remains with me. (later...) Researcher: Even though you're sharecropping, do you also pay field hands? How do you accomplish this? Through parimã or?... (Interjected by landlord: Why do you spend the rice so quickly? 32 Tenant: Because we eat too much. If we can eat about 7 or 8 roëis then we might finish up to 2 manas of grain.) Tenant: No, I needed to get help through parimã in the past, but this year I couldn't get any help through parimã. I say here truly, I had Rs. 1000 before the planting but after I found I had only Rs. 300 left. Landlord: How did you call the women for planting our rice land? [Question went unanswered.] Interjected by Landlord‘s Brother: Who paid the roparnis? We or he [tenant]? Landlord: We paid them Rs. 10 plus hilauri [tip].)xiii *1 mana = approx. .6 liter *Rs. 27 = U.S.$1.00 approx. in 1990 The domination - subordination of the landlord - sharecropper relationship influenced the conversation with the sharecropper often defending himself. In reply to the Landlord’s question about spending rice quickly, the sharecropper replied that he eats “too much”, yet he contradicts this statement by saying they eat ‘up to 2 manas of rice’ per day. This is not overeating but considered the standard amount a farmer should eat per day. Thus the tenant is actually defending himself by saying that he does not waste grain for consumption. In the second embedded question, the landlord’s brother questions the truthfulness of the tenant. After the tenant says he spent Rs. 700 in the recent transplant of rice operation, the landlord replies that it was he, not the tenant, who pays the roparnis, female transplanters.xiv 33 Mr. Khatri responded that he could not get help through labor exchange (parimã) so he switched to free labor (jãla). Farmers chose to work for wages rather than reciprocate their labor with Mr. Khatri. Why? Possibly because there are more commodities to be purchased, such as clothes, liquor, paper, and medicines. Perhaps the workers, mostly women, have fewer opportunities to earn cash since most do not migrate or trade on a large scale. Because there are increased opportunities in the economy to purchase goods portered from the Nepalese lowlands and India whereas grains only can be grown, consumed, stored or fed to guests. Cash represents surplus; grain merely subsistence since few households sell grain. This conversation is interesting in the way Mr. Khatri calculates his harvests and wishes to point out how successful his family is at keeping enough food to feed their household. His family has "no problems with food" which he fulfills from his Adhiyå duties. He gives estimates of crop yields, including yields of about 60 muri paddy and wheat of which he keeps a little over 30 muri, his reliance on his family's own parcels of dryland which produce a little paddy and corn, and his supply in the middle of the season of yet 4 muri wheat which will "easily" last them till corn harvests in August/September. Hilauri, the "mud gratuity" to the women and men at the end of the day represents more than a simple gratuity. This is a token of gratitude, a mana of grain or more often tobacco and rãksi, for each days' labor, and it is an important means to bond the landowner with the worker women. The women will complain and call the owner greedy and mean-spirited if he/she does not provide the token gift. Mr. Khatri later states that the custom is old, but the recent switch from grain and tobacco to alcohol gifts has made the planter - owner (roparni - sauji) relationship strained. Often, hired women demand to quit early and wish to drink more than the sauji (landowner or landholder) can afford. Perhaps the hilauri tie has been historically similar to the way in which bonded laborers kept a firm tie with their patrons. The bonded laborer accepts a 34 loan he/she can never repay; the roparni takes a small gift which however slight, obligates her to work again for the farmer. Stories about land disputes form a part of almost everyone's history in Jãjarkoë . Since I lived next door to a lawyer (wokil), I heard grievances related to land disputes. One tenant told about one legal case involving a crops, beating, and cows: Our cows had eaten Mr. Thãkuri’s son's crop. Then Mr. Thãkuri’s son met my son on the way and inquired nastily about the cows and the incident. My son told him, 'well, our cows ate your crops but not much as you've demonstrated'. Suddenly the son of the Thãkuri hit my son on the forehead with a Kute [hoe]. After that blood poured from his forehead and I went straight to the police office and gave a formal complaint [about the beating] to check out the accident. Then the injury was checked out by the doctor and I won that case." [Tape 13, Side A: 1990] Sharecroppers often have to negotiate verbal and occasionally physical abuses by elite Thakuris and other high castes. Disputes have many connotations; they can signal social status, willingness to enter into political battle, ability to fight for more material goods, or simply defense of a charge. Land disputes are open arenas for creating and enlarging one's political and material ambitions. Land disputes are like life games for adult men. One large landlord of Jãjarkoëi nobility has so many cases filed against him, and has filed so many cases against others, that he literally is in court every week of his life. I consulted him occasionally about decades' old cases because he easily recalled circumstances surrounding written court documents. 35 Legal cases often deal explicitly with Adhiyå dispute.xv In this case, instigated by a local tax collector (talukdãr) it appeared to be a simple case of a sharecropper withholding of his portion due the landlord. The litigant claimed, "I [the litigant] inherited a parcel of land from Prakash (A0) and rented it to the defendant in an Adhiyå agreement. The agreement, like usual Adhiyå stipulated that the defendant give the litigant one-half the total production of rice. In 1985 the defendant didn't give the produce and the litigant refused to continue the agreement. In the spring of 1986 the litigant heard from friends that the defendant planted on the land and so the litigant wants to get the land back and stop the defendant from farming on this parcel. Mr. Shah, the litigant, lives just an hours' walk from the Bazaar and his Thãkuri family has been in the area “since the beginning.” The sharecropper is a Bãhun from the Bãhun enclave of Jaktipur, about 3 hours' away, where two centuries ago and prior the Kings of Jãjarkoë lived.xvi As the court contestants battle, they bring their heritage with them. Both the litigating Thãkuri, of nobility, and the defending Bãhun, of literate elite background, had cultural and economic resources to win the case. The defendant claimed that, "Prakash did own the land parcel and he had two wives. From the first wife he had one son, Rajesh, A1, who in turn had three sons, A2a and A2b, and A2c, who is the litigant. I [defendant] bought the land from Rajesh, who is the son of Prakash through his first wife, in 1966 and have been using the land continually ever since. 36 The litigant is the local talukdãr or tax collector and absentee landlord (or rather, claimed to be one). He has ties to the Land Reform Office, as tax collector, and ancestral ties to land near Jaktipur. He has material, cultural, and social resources in land, administrative/ legal literacy, and political position. The talukdãr has enormous advantage over illiterate people; he can manipulate tax records, a crucial means of proving ownership of land. Unfortunately for the litigant, his witnesses (såchhi) did not corroborate his story and his past tax work was fraudulent. It turned out that the tax collector submitted false tax bills to the Land Reform Office [Mal Kaïalaya, formerly Bhumi Sudhãr Kaïalaya].xvii The Court found that the litigant not only submitted false tax bills to the Land Reform Office but had also done so in the past. The litigant was fined [jãribanã ] Rs. 25 for submitting an illegal claim.xviii Dudhko adhiyå We have read about land tenure using Adhiyå relationships but livestock also constitute a form of wealth and can be part of an Adhiyå agreement. The dudhko Adhiyå or milk share system is similar to landed forms of Adhiyå in that the resource is handed over to shepherds (gwãlo-gwãli) who manage a herd and gives the owner part of the produce. Shepherds usually receive half of the dairy or a fee when the owner earns cash by selling dairy products. One Bãhun owner said their family gives shepherds cloth and money, and the shepherd is also the Bãhuns' ironsmith family using khalo. Usually shepherds keep any male buffalo (rãngo) that are born. When baby male buffalo are born, low caste shepherds kill the buffalo and dry the meat. Newborns can be worth up to Rs. 800 so they are an important meat source. High castes normally abstain from regularly eating buffalo meat except with liquor, so they normally buy meat from low castes rather than pollute themselves with killing buffalo. 37 Many Bãhuns have a shepherding arrangement with low castes because they cannot care for animals they receive as payment for jajmãni services. Bãhuns, unlike Thakurs or Chetris, cannot pass work to a poor relative since it would violate caste regulations. Families surrounding the District Center (District Center) who do not have big enough families to take care of herds usually contract with shepherds. The District Center and peripheral regions do not have forest resources to maintain a livestock hut (goëh) nearby. And District Center high castes are already involved in other income earning exploits such as government work, trade, a tea stall, or vegetable farming. The District Center draws a relatively large amount of dairy each day from the surrounding countryside in order to keep tea stalls, wealthy families, and government officials satisfied, so dudhko Adhiyå is an important indigenous labor practice. In late summer of 1990 I asked my milkboy, Kãncha, to accompany me on visits to surrounding dairy farming families in the region peripheral to Khalaÿgã. Many dairy farmers in the Jeula area had only one to three milk giving buffalo on their farms. Extra buffalo were sent to dudhko Adhiyå shepherds living on the next ridge (lekh) to the north, which is still covered with forest. Jeula farmers with extra buffalo and extra children sent their older children to a goëh with their livestock in the northern ridges. Cows in Jãjarkoë give only about a kilogram of milk per day when they're nursing and goats even less. Normally farmers mix cows' milk with buffalo milk and then process it. Occasionally farmers reserve cows' milk, one of the most pure substances in Nepalese cosmology, and make ghiu (clarified butter) or curd for special occasions such as a naming ceremony. One of the Jeula farmers had a cow which produced 4 mana, about 4 pounds, of milk per day; this was the highest production I recorded. If the owner keeps his/her buffalo near Khalaÿgã, at least half of production goes to Khalaÿgã on a daily basis. As one farmer said, 'one mana to the hill (District Center) in the morning and 1 mana for us at night'. Usually the farmer has a contract with a tea stall owner or a 38 wealthy family in the bazaar. The farmers’ children, usually girls, bring up milk and curd each morning to be consumed by District Center residents. District Center households and tea stalls keep a contract with the girls and pay on a weekly or monthly basis. Strict accounts are kept of whether milk was delivered each day as promised. District Center consumers have no contract with girls that bring milk on an irregular basis. Girls from over 3 hours away bring curd, carrying two or three containers (thekis ), of about 2.5 liter (dhãrni) each. Dairy products are highly valued in the District Center since no shops regularly carry perishables like curd, eggs, radish, broccoli, cauliflower, ginger or even garlic. District Center households are expected to grow these in their gardens (bari , kamat ). Since most families avoid chicken raising (polluting to high castes), eggs are seldom part of the District Center household diet. Most Khala¨ngã residents get milk, curd, ghiu, and meat, but rarely other dairy byproducts. On dairy farms however, many products are made and consumed in small amounts. These include nauni/launi (butter), ëhar (cream) and mahi (buttermilk); galim and karãni (whey and milk curds). Dairy production is terribly dependent on surrounding centers whether they be urban or rural, so that in rural parts of Jãjarkoë , it‘s not possible to produce milk for sale; there's no central place to sell it. Instead, farmers make clarified butter for sale into Jumla, Khala¨ngã, Nepalganj, and along migration routes. In Bishop's records (1990) of traded imports coming into Jumla District Center in 1970 for example, Jãjarkoëis brought in 1,328 kgs clarified butter. These stocks of dairy come from northern parts of the district, whereas southern stocks of dairy tend to move southwards. Livestock farming, and farming in general is labor intensive. Some men seek second and third wives who can take over the requirements of a busy and productive farm. Many men and women wish to be part of a family that owns many livestock, enough land, and even experiments with developed fruit and vegetable production. Such a family is generally seen as successful in 39 farming. Occasionally women leave one husband and go to another to be part of a successful farm family. This is one of the reasons for using jãri which does not fit Hindu ideals. Free and Casual Labor: Jãla and Baure As noted earlier, artisans tend to be laborers (.543 correlation). Generally this means a household member of an artisan has done or does jãla or baure. Jãla, baure, khalo, and other indigenous labor practices are closely related and used according to conditions of a particular task. A legal Nepali dictionary defines jãla broadly as 'worker for an owner or doing business for one's own sake or taking some sort of action on behalf of various persons for an approved duration' [Singh, 1981: 229]. My conversations with interviewed people indicate that jãladãri (free laborers) work on a daily basis, are not employed for long term by an employer, and jãladãri (workers) seek work intermittently but not permanently. Wages in Jãjarkoë are fairly uniform. Jãla free laborers are paid in cash and men are paid more, up to Rs.55/day if the work involves skilled labor such as carpentry. Women are paid up to Rs. 30/day even if they do some skilled labor, such as cooking for the crew, or unskilled labor, such as plastering, carrying stone, hauling logs. Free laborers generally complained that they were cheated out of their pay, they had to bargain hard to get it, or they were not paid for months after the work began. Jãladãri tend to work on government projects, portering, and any rather impersonal works. Jãla free laborers often work for people they do not know personally. Jãladãri have little power of coercion over their employers. Free laborers sometimes form work bond with other laborers to ensure that they get paid. Seasonal migrants, for example, use the organizational services of a met, group negotiator, and katuwãl, messenger. The met negotiates with the employer on behalf of the workers and sometimes does the accounts of work-days for the 40 employer. The katuwãl informs the laborers of good employers, honest mets, secure work, amount they will get paid, bus routes and fees, etc. One group of irrigation workers in Jãjarkoë were hired as unskilled laborers to dig a canal and pour the concrete mixture. They were not paid for months after their work had begun. Since the workers were not paid, many dropped out of the project. The workers had to meet immediate daily food demands so they turned to other daily labor, tended their fields, and fished in the Bheri River. After five months the irrigation project overseer got tarred and feathered by the workers! Eventually all workers were reportedly paid. Private households on occasion hire free laborers, such as carpenters, porters, and plasterers. But households which themselves are not composed of full time salaried wage earning families cannot afford to hire full time daily laborers. Households hire wage laborers for short term work, e.g. to send tins of clarified butter south to the terai, to carry new slate from a local mine for roofing, or to clean and replaster the house for an upcoming feast. Rather than paying a full daily wage using jãladãri, most households turn to casual labor, reciprocity, and gifts of labor. Casual labor (baure, or 'called labor') differs from free labor in that workers primarily do agricultural labor, payment is in grain, food, and cash, and casual workers are recruited from mostly low caste neighbors. The rates of payment for baure in 1989-90 were about 2-3 mana grain/day plus simple meals, Rs. 20 plus three meals, or Rs. 20-25 plus a snack, depending on village customs. Women are paid less, about Rs. 15 and children who work or just accompany their parents are given only meals. For rice transplanting work which is labor intensive, women are often paid a tip called hilauri or literally “mud gratuity” which consists of a glass of rãksi liquor or Rs. 5-10 in addition to wages. They are also referred to as roparni, "female planters." Men do not transplant rice but do the plow work and are referred to as "haliyã." 41 Casual labor perhaps arose in Jãjarkoë out of landowners and patrons’ needs to have a dependable workforce yet not be obligated to workers. Note that landowners in Jãjarkoë do not usually have huge estates; about one hectare constitutes a successful landowning household. In addition to agricultural labor, casual laborers build houses, walls, terraces, do woodworking, carpentry, carry stone or other work that required heavy lifting. Men engaged in plowing, woodworking, carpentry, carrying stone especially. Women do casual labor especially for planting, transplanting and weeding. In jãla (daily labor) laborers typically work for a longer contractual period of time compared to baure. People use the terms interchangeably however. Mr. Gharti in northern Jãjarkoë explained the difference in his region between casual labor (baure) and parimã labor reciprocity. Mr. Gharti had just come back from his livestock shelter (goëh) on a nearby ridge, carrying birch bark, rhubarb, wild greens, and milk. His daughter Rupa and I had hired a Kami skilled laborer to carry wood logs from the forest and build a large weaving loom. We were also using the local katuwãl village messenger to tell local households that we needed labor help with the corn fields. Mr Gharti explained what kinds of labor I was seeking: G: We do labor reciprocity (parimã) for only one or two days. For [big] work, there is baure. We call one person [low caste] and their people come and on a daily basis we use baure. We don't use baure for small work but for big work. When they work they eat, they just eat and leave. We give baure workers only food and not money. Jana: Last time [you used casual laborers] did many people come? Who were they? Gharti: Blacksmith caste families come here and Leatherworker caste members also, low castes come for baure. If we get them work for five or ten days then they will take [grain 42 or cash] wages [not just food]. We give them beer [jãï: fermented grain], bread [roëi], cooked pulses, vegetables [tarkãri]. Yogurt also, but we do not give curd to Blacksmith and Leather worker caste families. Mr. Gharti demonstrated that casual labor and parimã labor reciprocity can overlap in agricultural tasks. To artificially segregate labor forms causes researchers to miss the point that the social organization of indigenous labor is one continuous set of productive choices. Jajmãni is part of baure is part of adhiyå is part of jãla is part of parimã is part of sahayog is part of many labor choices. Conclusions In this chapter I have traced three types of labor (sharecropping, daily or free labor, and casual labor) in an effort to understand the worker's world. In keeping with the rest of the dissertation, I stressed that jajmãni is not segregated in any way from other labor forms. Artisanship is one aspect of worker though it is connected to other unskilled work. Almost all artisan households also do unskilled labor for other households. Second, I used both qualitative and quantitative data to show that the social organization of indigenous labor is generally exploitative of the worker. From interviews we saw the subordinate demeanors of a sharecropper with his landlord and that workers often practice rule bending to adjust to high caste and elite proscriptions. The use of love marriage, matrilocality, brideservice, and remarriage are examples of rule bending by workers. From quantitative portrayals we notice several points about workers. First, low castes are usually the workers, even when they constitute the minority population-wise. Second, regardless of caste, workers live lower qualities of life. They own less land, eat less food, are illiterate, and 43 do not use development facilities as much as high castes and "Non-worker" households. In terms of local social classes, workers come primarily from landless laborer and laborer-cultivator strata. As I named a research report entitled, Adhiyan is more than 'half,' an ethos of half ("adhe") to the owner, half to the worker obfuscates real relations of unequal exchange. Adhiyå workers are sharecroppers who are likely to give more of their surplus, lose part of their quality of life, lose opportunities to partake of development services, and suffer malnutrition, discrimination, and near landlessness. The principles of adhe (half) and sajhe (to share) constantly confront the worker in their goals to meet subsistence. 'Half to the Owner and Half to the worker' captures the ethos of resource distribution. The idea that things had to be made "equal" in a hierarchical society stratified by both caste and class is actually quite a feat. Even the local Communist Party outreach worker mentioned how he thought the half-half (adhe) principle was fair: "That is the way we have always done it," he said. Another ethic which is prominent in Jãjarkoë is that a fair exchange should fulfill the subsistence needs of the less powerful partner. workers try to earn enough to feed the family or store enough till the next harvest. They do not openly express the desire to create a surplus. This ethic fits well the ideology of patronage. In the next Chapter I analyze two other permutations in the social organization of indigenous labor, namely, reciprocal labor and gifts of labor. N otes to Chapter Six iIn my socio-economic surveys I asked several questions to determine if the surveyed household might fall into the worker social category. Specifically I asked 1) Have you or any of your family members practiced migrancy? 2) Have you or any members of your household practiced sharecropping? 3) Have you or any members of your family worked for others as artisans (khalo khãne mãnchhe), casual laborer (baure), or daily labor (jãla)? If an interviewed person responded affirmatively, their household was 44 probably a "worker" household and I asked follow-up questions to verify worker status. I neglected to ask if interviewees had worked as bonded laborers (haliyã) mostly because it was rude and I felt I could find out about such circumstances indirectly through speaking with neighbors. Also, artisans arguably own their own means of production (goldsmithing, ironsmithing, coppersmithing tools, pottery wheels, sewing machines, etc.). Yet artisans are treated so poorly, cannot command more than subsistence levels of remuneration for their work, and they are dependent on grain from patron / landlords. Thus analytically I join artisans (skilled laborers) with unskilled laborers to label both "workers". ii According to J. Thompson (personal communication), elites in Kathmandu say that dowry is in fact not a Nepalese custom but one borrowed from India. iii iv v In Jãjarkoë a child's feeding ceremony refers to his/her first taste of food other than mother's milk. All the relatives and neighbors are invited, they contribute donations of money, and the family puts on a feast. The family cooks for the party and cooks a small amount of all foods the child will become used to as he or she grows older. These foods include meats, fish varieties, various types of dairy, some vegetables, rice and other grains. Each type of food is brought to the child's lips though the child doesn't actually eat every type of food. Boys have their feeding ceremonies slightly earlier than girls at about four to five months; girls at about five to six months of age. In one account (INSAN 1992) jãri was criticized because the second husbands often take loans to pay the first husbands and the loans drive the new husbands into debt. The men become bonded laborers from default on their loans. While the wives certainly don't want to cause their new husbands to become bonded laborers, it does not seem exploitative of women! All of the love marriage examples are taken from Rawotgaun Village Interviews, 1990. All names have been changed. vi According to J. Thompson (personal conversation) elites do not really follow the proscribed marriage rules either. It might be pertinent to recognize patterns of difference among elites and commoners in terms of deviance from proscribed marriage rules. vii Interestingly, low caste households in northern regions of Jãjarkoë earn only about 50% of total earnings from labor. Again, historical circumstances which enable these more northerly groups to trade with Jumla and Dolpa may account for their emphasis on trade. viii Average grain production of low caste families in survey sample is 7.89 muris yet a family of about eight people, with an average consumption size in survey sample of 5.38 adult units, needs an estimated 24.52 muri of grain (5.38 adult consumption units x 2 mana husked grain per day x 365 days = 3927.4 mana = 490.9 pathi = 24.5 muri). 45 Consumption size refers to how much an adult eats (Metz 1989a). Age Consumption Unit 0-2 years 0.00 3-5 .25 6-9 .50 10-15 .75 16-50 1.00 51-60 .75 61-70 .50 71+ .25 ix x For adhiyå, the term "sajhe" meaning to share, partner, cooperate is also used. Throughout Nepal the Adhiyå - birtã system has historically been of great importance in class relations. The combination of birtã and sharecropping created a multitiered set of class relations which consisted of the government at the top, birta absentee landlords a step below, landholders beneath the prior level, and the actual cultivators at the bottom. Regmi [1978:319] describes this as a trend toward "subinfeudation" xi Jagir tenures were land grants to government employees, guards, administrators, etc. who worked outside their home districts. Government workers received land in lieu of wages. xii For details see M.C. Regmi 1971. W. Theisenhusen 1988 also gives a good overview of government actions since the 1964 legislation. See also IDS, 1985; 1986 and Zaman, 1973. xiii xiv xv This interview is also discussed in Fortier 1993. Usually the sharecropper, not the landlord, pays all workers. To understand both sides of a land dispute, my research assistants and I went to the Law Court Office (Adalit Goswara) in the DC. I was chary of actually listening to ongoing disputes, I wouldn't have understood much of the legal jargon in proceedings and I certainly wouldn't be allowed to tape record. So Gyaneshwor, Dharma and I summarized land disputes in the Court Office archives. The records of cases have several documents attached, including the litigant's claim, the defendent's claim, and supporting documents such as ownership records, title transfers, deeds of sale, tax records, and judgements. It takes a lawyer to interpret legal documents since they are written in a legalese Nepali jargon with many Sanskritic and Persian influences. Our goal was to extract a sample of documents from the archives and record basic information from each side of a case. I would have liked to have collected more than the forty cases which we compiled, but we couldn't continue talking to the Court Officers while they worked. 46 xvi This is the epicenter of old Brahmin tradition in Jãjarkoë. Today there are still stone stellae in Jaktipur attesting to the Jãjarkoë Kings' allegiance to the Khasa and Malla Kingdom which covered all of western Nepal [circa 1100-1400 A.D.]. xvii The King's Property Office ended in 1960 but it's date of establishment I don't know. The Land Office [Bhumi Sudhãr Kaïalaya], established in 1964, succeeded the King's Property Office. The Land Reform Office [Mal Kaïalaya], established in 1974/75, has taken over the Land Office's duties. xviii Persons rarely are fined in land disputes except if there has been illegal occupation of land. In 1985 exchange rate was about Rs. 16 = U.S. 1.00. Inflation is about 15%/annum. 290 7 PARIMÃ AND SAHAYOG: EGALITARIAN EXCHANGE IN A HIERARCHICAL SOCIETY J: What's parimã like? G: Today we worked in your home then tomorrow you came in our home to work. Mr. Gharti Somdãda, 1990 Introduction It becomes more apparent as one explores the nature of khalo, jajmãni, adhiyå, and riÿ-diÿ that indigenous labor practices form a network of efficient alternatives for agricultural and livestock production. In this Chapter I discuss the nature of ideally egalitarian indigenous labor practices known as parimã (labor exchange) and sahayog(gifts of labor). My main contention is that parimã and sahayog provide two necessary labor strategies for successful management of agricultural production. Farmers use informal labor practices of parimã and sahayog at crucial times of the agricultural season. These egalitarian strategies are contingent on a number of farming constraints which will be discussed in the chapter. Smallholders often use parimã, sahayog, and baure during a single farming operation. Farmers create a hierarchy of labor alternatives, and prefer one type of labor over others, indicating knowledge of distinctions between relative efficiencies of labor forms. A second goal of this Chapter is to explore the interface between cooperation and exploitationi between households which use parimã and sahayog. I hold that labor reciprocity between households tends to occur between households with roughly balanced or equal amounts of resources and social status. Balanced reciprocity occurs among households which are related through extended kinship, 'Domestic Kin' (Stack 1974). When labor reciprocity 291 occurs between households of unequal status or resources, parimã and sahayog become forms of unequal exchange, with the dominant partner obtaining more labor than the other. I will present descriptions of both egalitarian and exploitative parimã and sahayog relationships, and discuss why both exist within an ideology of equal exchange. In the next section of this chapter, I describe a rice transplanting day in close detail. I pay special attention to how the land owners manage parimã, sahayog, and baure. I conclude that efficient agricultural production relies on a combination of labor practices. To compare my observations with residents of Jãjarkoë, I describe interviews in which informants define parimã, sahayog, and baure. I pay close attention to the informants' ideals of parimã, sahayog, and baure in order to compare their descriptions with my own observations of labor exchange. From these descriptions I conclude that inter-caste labor relationships are hierarchical even when using parimã and sahayog. Intra-caste relationships are patterned according to the egalitarian ideals of parimã and sahayog as stated by informants. In Section Two I develop a profile of parimã users versus non-users. Using both descriptive and statistical profiles, I conclude that parimã users represent the middle range of socioeconomic positions while households which do not use parimã are split between the wealthiest and poorest households. I hold that parimã is an efficient labor choice when smallholders have medium amounts of resources or capital. Secondly, farmers use parimã and sahayog for considerable amounts of work. In one rural village, households were estimated to receive labor from neighbors 37 days per year. In this Chapter the question of efficiency is important, perhaps more than in other chapters. As I outlined in Chapter Three, ideologies of form, such as the ideology of efficiency, take their structure and meaning given their particular production form. Since we are dealing with a production form of patronage, the ideology of efficiency is semantically and realistically different from that of a capitalist paradigm. Even though I measured productive time in labor days, this is not the way a farmer might necessarily estimate efficiency. An efficient farmer 292 might be described as one who is honest (sojo), clever (chalak), and finds things to do when a job is finished (not alchhi, lazy). In line with these moral characteristics, a farmer should apply parimã, baure (call laborers), and give or receive sahayog in order to fill her working day with productive activities. Overall, efficiency, from what I have experienced in Jãjarkoë, seems to be estimated by filling one's day with productive work. It is not estimated by hours of work, money earned, or size of harvest. Rice Transplanting Day: The Karki Family's Experience Rice transplanting day actually begins long before June when neighbors come together for muddy camaraderie. Piecing together the voices of many women and men who contributed labor to one household's rice fields, I will describe one of the most important agricultural events in a farming household's year of work. On a cloudy and chilly April day, after calling two Karki relatives and children of their local ironsmith, Mr. and Mrs. Karki walked to their thirty parcels of khet (land capable of being irrigated)ii. Mr. Karki instructed the Kami boy to harrow two land parcels while the Kami girl broke up dirt clods and picked out weeds. Dried wheat stalks, leftover from the winter harvest, lay broken on the ground. The Kãmi’s oxen dug the earth about one hat (forearm length) deep, plowing wheat mulch into the earth. The oxen wore wooden yokes and the plow tips were outfitted in iron made by the Kami ironsmith. I asked Mr. Karki about his role in preparing the spring soil. Mr. Karki explained, "It is not that I am a Brãhman and cannot plow ... but I'm old, I live in the District Capital, and I can not care for oxen. The khalo khãne mãnchhe, our Kami, has oxen and so I call them and do baure." I asked Mrs. Karki if the Kãmis were also sharecroppers. "Yes, we do have three mohi (sharecroppers). We don't have enough family so we use adhiyå with two Karki relatives and one Kami." She produced two sacks of rice reserved from the previous season. "All this rice seed comes from our own harvest from last year. Two of the sharecroppers have also brought rice seed. We sometimes buy bikãsi 293 (developed) seed from the Agricultural Development Office but this seed is all local." The sharecroppers should ideally provide all the other inputs of fertilizer, weeding, and protection. Together the Karkis and Kãmis fertilized with buffalo dung, spread out the dirt evenly, planted rice seed, and covered the ground with leftover wheat stalks. After watering lightly but not soaking, the rice nursery was started. These two beds would grow until the sprouts were half a meter tall, growing into mid-June. That spring day Mrs. Karki, her daughter-in-law (buhãri), and her husband's sister cooked a perfect breakfast. They boiled up mixed lentils into a thick stew. They patted and fried wheat roti breads that were thick and chewy rather than thin and delicate. They made a special achãr pickle of ground sesame seeds with mustard oil and coriander. Everyone, women and men, drank rãksi of distilled rice and smoked cigarettes in the late afternoon. As the Kami youths prepared to leave on the second day, the sharecropper handed the boys Rs. 50 and the girls Rs. 40 each. He told them to come back in mid-June for the transplanting. When the monsoon rains started in early June, the tiny stream which normally trickled out of the southern sloping hill sprouted into a thick dependable source of irrigation water. The sharecroppers who mostly worked in the valley north of the District Center held a meeting. A few of the landowners were also present. They discussed who would receive water first and what the order of turns would be. They chose to each build up their own containment walls and channel off the water according to who was transplanting each day. Many farmers had access to mñl, springs pouring out of the crevices in the hill directly above their valley plots. The springs were important sources of water since they held the most pure water, for drinking and not for washing clothes and animals. Mrs. Karki 's buhãri (daughter-in-law) and their sharecropping relative, Rita, used the spring water to cook and they carried clay pots full of clean spring water into their second house near the fields. Preparing for rice transplanting day, Buhãri and Rita fashioned hundreds of leaf plates. They had much cooking work to prepare before dhan ropne din (rice transplanting day) 294 since they would feed about thirty people for several days. Buhãri and the Karki friends gathered sesame seed from their alley crops and ground the seed into paste. They collected a dozen pumpkins and cut them into pieces. They ground one and a half muri wheat into flour at the water mill and stored it in the valley house. They collected firewood to last for extended cooking. They went around to the local water buffalo owners and negotiated for extra milk and yogurt. Since they were competing with their neighbors, getting the dairy was difficult. The Karkis like goat meat so they slaughtered one of their own. Finally they procured rãksi from a low caste woman in the District Center. Dhan ropne din used to be even more of a festive atmosphere when the Damãi tailors came around and played music and sang while people worked. But this year the Damãi were too busy with sewing and didn't plan to come out to the fields. Visiting the Nepal Bank Limited to take money from the bachat, savings account was Rita's final errand before the event. This would be the biggest outlay of money on agriculture since the sharecroppers had to provide about Rs. 700 for baure workers. The Karkis did parimã and sahayog with their extended family and didn't spend any money on baure workers. During the last three weeks of June the Karkis and sharecroppers were constantly busy. They either were preparing for their own rice transplanting, or they were at the fields of one of their neighbors. Since school was out in the District Center, the teenagers liked to give sahayog to the landowners and sharecroppers in the valley. Each morning groups of up to a dozen youth would band together and saunter down. Given that the teenagers were doing this for fun, they did more laughing, throwing mud, and teasing of each other than actual planting. They managed to transplant one or two parcels of khet land while their parents, parimã participants, and baure workers finished off the vast majority of the work. One could say that the landowner's children and friends did some work but the baure workers really worked hard. On the first day of rice transplanting for the Karkis, work started early. By daybreak men had gathered at the khet land with their oxen. They harrowed (halnu)iii hard soil and with Kute (garden hoe) smoothed clumps of dirt. Two men rebuilt stone walls while two more men 295 channeled spring and stream water toward the loamy soil. Four men guided two pair of oxen onto the fields. One young Kami youth smiled as he held up a laëëhi (heavy stick) and beat the rump of the ox. The women sat under the pipal tree at a resting place (chautãri), restless and waiting. After the water flooded the higher parcels, the men got their first mud bathe. The oxen too became bathed in mud. All the men wore old cotton shorts and shirts while the women donned their oldest work clothes. By late morning the men had finished most upper terraces. Two older men meanwhile hoed carefully the rice nurseries and removed the young rice stalks. These they tied into bundles of about 300 seedlings. The older men carried the seedlings to prepared muddy smoothed khet parcels and deposited enough seedlings for approximately twenty-five seedlings per square foot. The women sitting at the chautãri shared a last cigarette. It was nearly nine A.M., time to begin setting rice stalks. The baure workers expected three full meals and Rs. 20 for their day of work. Mrs. Karki's relatives, all who came as parimã workers, were still sitting in the house by the field. They adjusted their clothes, cooked the morning meal, watched a baby, and chatted. This was one of the times when they could all catch up on news. By late morning the teenagers showed up, hungry and asking to eat before work. Actually, Mrs. Karki fully expected the youths to eat. When I protested that I wasn't hungry, buhãri pointed out that this is all part of dhãn ropne din; everyone had to eat a morning meal. As our group meandered to the fields by noon, the baure workers had already slapped rice stalks into five or six of the terraces. Soon the scene was one long succession of rice parcels in different stages of dress. The lowest parcels had oxen munching on stray pieces of grass, waiting to harrow. The parcels terraced just above were harrowed. The parcels above on a third level were muddy chunky plots with men waving garden hoes. The fourth level of terracing showed smooth waters with rice bundles dolloped on top. The fifth level was lined with a row of fifteen women, all bent over in human pyramid shapes, slapping rice stalks from bundles in their hands. The serious working women set roughly twenty-five seedlings into 296 place every ten seconds. By comparison, the teenagers and myself could only place ten seedlings in ten seconds. The higher terraces were sometimes not yet finished by the men and so the oxen could be found sometimes above the women transplanters and sometimes below them. Mr. Karki's eldest son, Shyam, now a landlord in his own right, had been known to drink rãksi excessively sometimes. This was one of those times, and he and his friends were obviously into the joy of farming in a different way than the workers. Shyam and his friends chatted with the sharecropper, offered him rãksi. They rode on the harrow and talked to the workers. They sported their new sunglasses and ready-made shorts imprinted with bold 'Marlboro' lettering in red and white. They especially liked borrowing my video camera. Since they were the 'bosses' they controlled the video camera for a portion of the day. Shyam and company ended their dhan ropne din happy, intoxicated, and complete muddy. Shyam's sister, Sita, unlike her brother, was less controlling and interacted nearly all the time with her parimã female relatives or the teenagers giving sahayog. Years' ago, Sita left her husband. She inherited a portion of land from her father, making her a landowner also. She has two sharecroppers and except for dhan ropne din, leaves nearly all of the work to them. Sita normally works as an educator for the Family Planning Office. From the above description one can see that simple labor reciprocity (parimã) is not always simple. When asked, people may say that they use parimã for rice transplanting. The reality is that households often use many more types of labor management than parimã. In this case the Karkis use sharecropping (adhiyå), the sharecroppers call casual laborers (baure ), and the local teenagers of elites donate gifts of labor (sahayog). The extended Karki domestic network does parimã. No one uses daily labor (jãla) and the landowners do not pay casual labors. From the above description one can also see that some social relationships are egalitarian while others are obviously hierarchical. Sita's relationships with her relatives who 297 donated parimã labor time are egalitarian. Sita, her mother, father, and hopefully brother will all donate labor for their network of neighbors and relatives with land in the valley. A more hierarchical relationship exists between the landowners, their low caste sharecroppers, and the casual laborers. These hierarchies might be based on caste affiliation but they are also based on labor category, land ownership, and gender. High castes, landowners, and men command more social control in their relationships with low castes, tenants, casual laborers and women. One nearly forgets that the divisions of labor based on age and gender are also at work in the day of rice transplanting. In some communities in Nepal this segregation apparently does not exist or is at least minimal, such as in Tamang communities (B. Campbell n.d.). In Jãjarkoë the eldest female and owner of the land directs the roparni, the female planters. She also tells the younger low caste males where to direct their plowing efforts. She sits on top of a large rock near a make-shift chautara (rest stop) and manages the workers. Her husband walks among the plowmen (hali) giving directions. Often he squats along an embankment and chats with his neighbors. The younger people, boys and girls join together, only segregated by caste. The younger people are almost all high caste relatives and they move together in a swarm from the rest stop to a muddy patch and back to the rest stop. As a management tool, Parimã is an ideal choice when a household owns a medium amount of land, has a medium-size family, engages in a labor intensive task, has no available cash, is under no time constraints, has the ability to share water resources with neighbors, is able to attend farming decision-making meetings, and lives near neighbors with similar circumstances. If one of these constraints changes, the household may opt for another labor strategy. If the household is under a time constraint, for example, it may opt to call in neighbors using baure and pay the workers in large meals and cash. Overall, the scene is an example of the management of several forms of labor (parimã, sahayog, baure, adhiyå) all labeled under the productive activity, 'rice planting day' (dhan ropne din). Asymmetrical relationships are minimized. Instead, rice transplanting day is 298 known as the time when farmers organize parimã, egalitarian labor reciprocity. Extended households strengthen their social bonds with each other by working together. But do Jãjarkoëi people see the same things as an outside observer of parimã, sahayog, and baure? Perhaps they do not recognize hierarchy and equality in their labor exchanges. In the next section I present emic descriptions of sahayog, parimã, and baure by Jãjarkoëis. I find that people interviewed give idealized renditions of egalitarian exchange which they negotiate with real circumstances of both symmetrical and asymmetrical exchanges. Parimã and Sahayog: Views of informants and Interviewees I learned about parimã during one of the first interviews I did with a dairy farmer in Jãjarkoë. Mr. Y. Karki, the local historian, introduced me to Bhabi Bahadur and his family who lived in a hamlet peripheral to the DC. Bhabi's family was poor. Their only asset was that they owned four buffalo and sold milk in the DC. Mrs. B. B. made us kir, a cooked mixture of milk and rice, as Bhabi explained their dairy farming. Bhabi's daughters just returned from delivering milk in the DC. The walk from Bhabi's house to Mr. Karki's was a full hour. At one point in our evening discussion I asked whether Bhabi worked together with his neighbors. I had never heard or read about parimã or sahayog but I was thinking about forms of cooperation which D. Messerschmidt had written about (1981). The local historian, eager to contribute, explained the custom of parimã.iv He said, "for planting farmers substitute work, called parimo" (ropãi lãgi[ko] kisãn haru le kãm saëëã mã, parimo baneko) Tape 2(A), 1986). He explained that Bhabi might work for ten days for other people, going each day to a neighbor's household and giving labor. On the eleventh day, neighbors would come and work on Bhabi's land. He added that all household members work- women, children, and men. Bhabi interjected that jãt matlab chhaina - "caste doesn't matter" - any caste can work on any other caste's land using parimã. 299 After some discussion, I asked the dairy farmer, "With whom exactly do you do parimã?" Bhabi replied that he had very little land. He didn't need to call neighbors because his own family's work was sufficient. In fact, he said, "I will do work for others. I am a kamdãr, a paid worker, but I personally do not do parimã." Bhabi's family was too poor to share labor resources with neighbors. Instead they could sell their labor or give it in sahayog. While parimã might be prevalent, only households with medium amounts of land take advantage of labor reciprocity. Bhabi has not enough large livestock either to exchange shepherding duties. His girls can manage the stock and join with other children doing the same, but the work is not overwhelming. Bhabi may want to "loan" his labor occasionally to a neighbor, however. As Tiké Badi, a neighbor, pointed out, parimã can be called by the loan form, sapat. If his neighbor can repay the 'loan' of labor, then the neighbors will work together. But if one neighbor has too little land to work on, there is no reason to exchange labor. Some families have too many resources for efficient use of parimã. In this case a family will downplay the importance of parimã. Muwadevi Rawal, a Chhetri high caste woman, surprised me in her attitude about parimã. Muwadevi is the household head, 80 years' old, and mother of four sons and one daughter. Visiting in Baisigaun village about one day's walk north of the DC, I talked with Muwadevi. She said (in paraphrase) Parimã is when you give work to me and I exchange it and give it back to you. You don't take money. Parimã is not like baure or jãla (daily labor). We would use parimã when we can not get baure workers. Personally, I think there's no real advantage to doing parimã, except that you don't have to give money. I like baure better because everyone can do the planting when they want to. Also if we do baure, we can get several household's khet fields done in only one day. [Interview Lah-6 '90, '93] Muwadevi speaks from the perspective of a village elite. With plenty of land they produce enough to feed everyone and even split the land among all four brothers. While they grow little surplus, they managed to sell about fifty-five dollars' worth of wheat, corn, lentils, clarified 300 butter, vegetable oil, and beans in 1992. This represented one of the few Baisigaun households which regularly sold produce.v In light of the household's economic strategies, Muwadevi preferred to give the many destitute low caste workers in the village the opportunity to work rather than negotiate with the large extended Rawal family for parimã . Muwadevi recognizes that there is no real added efficiency or time saved in doing parimã with her neighbors. D. Guillet (1980) suggested that this might be an advantage of group labor and labor exchange and thus these forms remain in Peru despite the inroads made by capitalist wage labor. In Nepal, labor exchange does not appear to be an increased form of efficient labor per se, but since it is an alternative among labor forms, it increases the farmer's options and in this way increases the farmer's productive efficiency. The overlap between parimã, sahayog, and baure can be slight, especially in rural villages with little money to pay workers. In the village of Somdãda two days' walk north of the DC Rupa Gharti's family used a combination of labor practices in their everyday farming operations. Rupa Gharti is a young woman who left her first husband and was not engaged when I stayed with her. She managed her parent's farm while they were up on the lekh (mountain ridge) tending cattle. Rupa always needed to do several tasks in only a few days. While I visited, we helped a carpenter build Rupa's loom frame for weaving. We cleaned out the cattle shed of Rupa's sister-in-law, Bhakti. We dug potatoes from the garden, made rãksi to drink, milled wheat for the coming week's meals, and set corn stalks. Rupa also helped me give thirteen interviews in Somdãda, a village of about 130 Magar households. We used sahayog with Bhakti and she gave us sahayog in the corn fields. We called Kami girls to help us using sahayog and fed them. We petitioned the village messenger, the katuwãl, to look for extra workers to help us. Rupa paid the Katuwãl (messenger) using the khalo system. She delivers several kilograms of grain at least twice each year to the Katuwãl. She paid the carpenter with grain as she would a daily laborer (kamdãr, jãladãr). 301 Walking along the path from Rupa's house to her fields above the community at 2700 meters, we passed baure workers building Rupa's uncle's new house. Later I asked Rupa's father about the difference between parimã and baure . Mr. Gharti explained, ...We do parimã for only 1 or 2 days. For [big] work, there's baure. We call one person and their people come and on a daily basis we use baure ...We don't use baure for small work but for big work. When they work they eat, they just eat and leave ...we give baure workers only food and not money. There is a noticeable disjunction between parimã and baure . Casual labor (baure) replaces labor reciprocity when a household needs help that takes many days, involves inter-caste relations, need not be repaid, and where food and money are proper payments rather than labor. In addition, casual labor (baure) is caste specific. Low caste men work for high castes but high castes never do baure for low castes. I asked, J: G: J: G: Last time [you used baure ] did many people come? Who were they? Blacksmith caste families come here and Leatherworker caste members also; low castes come for baure. If we get them work for 5 or 10 days then they will take wages [not just meals]...we give them alcohol (jaö: fermented grain to drink), bread (roëi: bread/chappatis), and cooked pulses or vegetables (tarkãri ). Curd also, but we don't give curd to Blacksmith and Leatherworker caste familiesvi. For baure what work did they do? They do plowing, digging (goïne), roofing (ghar dhune), cutting wood (khãt kãtne), carrying stone (ïhungã bokne). In Somdãda low caste men do most baure work while women do parimã. In other villages however, women were also called to do baure. Though parimã and baure are ideally egalitarian, in reality parimã and baure can be stratified. Low caste households never, in any surveys, reported calling for help from high caste households. They frequently reported receiving or trading labor with extended kin and less often with low castes outside their kinship networks. Figure 7.4 shows the directions of labor recruitment in parimã and baure. Figure 7.4: Parimã and Baure Labor Donations by Caste 302 High Caste Hi Caste Parima Lo Caste Low Caste Partner ideally donates work Partner actually donates work In reality high castes usually exchange parimã help with their relatives and other high caste neighbors. The work is largely segregated by caste and also maintains divisions of labor by gender and age. From observations of baure and interviewee's reports, the trend is for high castes to recruit low castes but never the reverse. Poor high castes may also be recruited for baure. High castes do not even pretend that they donate baure or sell their labor to low castes. Low castes do not exchange baure with each other labor since they cannot afford to pay workers Rs. 30/day/ worker. In a survey sample of 59 households in rural regions (RRS) no low castes hired labor while 47% of high caste households hired labor regularly (see Table 6.1). When inter-caste exchange occurs the wealthier household asymmetrically receives more labor/benefits from the less powerful partner. This may be called paternalism, or in Nepãli, ãfno manche. Paternalism has been discussed by D. B. Bista (1992). He decries ãfno manche as a problematic relationship which prevents development in Nepal. His arguments are sound, logical, and it seems clear that nepotism, favoritism, and/or paternalism do provide the bases for much corruption in government offices, development offices, and contracting. In the 303 relationship between wealthy high caste farmer and others, ãfno manche implies a political relationship of rule-giver to weaker partners who obey rules. Even more adaptable than parimã or baure, the most fluid form of labor recruitment is sahayog, gifts of labor. From speaking of sahayog with informants and interviewees, I found a range of meanings which depended much on the social position of the speaker. When speaking with Tej Bahadur, an older schoolmaster, he described sahayog as kriyakap (kriyakalap), meaning a kind deed which connotes religious merit. I asked him to explain, and he said (paraphrasing), Sahayog means to help another person without taking money. I brought medicine for P.L. Karki when he was ill and worked for him for three days. He gave me food but not money. ... Sahayog is generally an equal arrangement and we don't have a problem with keeping the relationship this way. As a teacher it is my duty to do Sahayog. I feel that teaching about bikãsivii in itself, or about new knowledge, is my way of giving Sahayog. (LS '93; DCS #3) As a teacher who has left farming, Tej Bahadur invests sahayog with new meaning. When a household is wealthy and has left farming to others, they still do sahayog. One young woman, Mantikala, remembered that she had recently given sahayog for her neighbor's wedding. She said, During marriage time we [the younger female relatives] go to the family who is conducting the marriage and help cook, make plates, make the marriage things. Sahayog is good because we don't need any money when we do sahayog. Our social relations become stronger with our neighbors. Sahayog is really not any different than parimã. (LS '93; DCS #3) For a great number of households that I interviewed, sahayog was an egalitarian relationship that made people feel a sense of community and coherence with their neighbors and relatives. This clique of female neighbors included Brãhman, Thãkuri, and Chhetri women with similar high living standards. 304 Archetypal sahayog relationships occurred among relatives of the same caste doing agricultural labor. Range Sunãr gave an example of his sahayog relationships: I give sahayog when my neighbors are suffering hard times. We help by working in the fields and around the house. My neighbors ask when they need help. Women work in the fields and men do too. Children carry water, wood, and light fires. I gave help to three neighbors recently. One was a Sunãr who I helped with planting. It took three days and Mrs. Sunãr gave me food. ... I helped a second family recently too, a Thãkuri family; they're a relative of ours [through marriage? fictive kin?]. We helped them with planting for 2 days. They gave us food and Rs. 40/day. This was just like baure actually. I've helped this family at least three times before. The third family we recently helped was another Sunãr relative. We planted for 3 days and received food but no money. We help them all the time, at least three or four times each year. (RRS Dal #6; LS'93) As Range pointed out, when they did sahayog for relatives of their own caste the labor was reciprocal and egalitarian. Range’s family received help from a Sunãr relative for their own rice planting. But giving labor to Thãkuri high castes actually is a hierarchical relationship and the Sunars received money in exchange for their 'gifts of labor.' One normally mitigates their needs to sell labor. Here Range used the euphemism sahayog to mitigate the asymmetry of the labor relationship. Sometimes sahayog is overtly hierarchical, with each partner calculating a return of money or political favor. A Jaiselu healerviii who was curing my research assistant's ankle complained how his sahayog was not being reciprocated. He explained that his mit buwa, fictive father, was a very important man, the Mukhiyã (headman) of Chiruigaun village. Lately, the Jaiselu had given the Mukhiyã much help. It was the season to collect vegetable oil nuts from the chiuri tree. The Jaiselu worked for three days collecting nuts and gave them all to the Mukhiyã's daughter, Indrakãli. As with normal sahayog relationships Indrakãli gave the Jaiselu three meals but no money or grain payment. Yet the Mukhiyã had not given the Jaiselu any 305 political favors or help recently. It seemed to me that the relationship was one of patronage more that of egalitarian madati (friends who help each other). Because I hear about sahayog relationships usually from only one partner, either the donor or the receiver, I can merely hypothesis that gifts of labor are unequal between partners with unequal composite capitals. In the following example, a Thãkuri high caste man described gifts of labor that his family recently gave and received. He said of sahayog, People work in fields and help others who cannot help themselves. Women plant, cook, weed, and carry stones. Men plow, do fieldwork, carry things, and do digging. Children can carry water, wood, and light fires. My Didju (sister, married) [named Mobi] recently planted rice for a Rawal family. Mobi planted seed, dug earth, and guided people home. She worked for 4 days and the Rawal family gave her food but nothing else. Called laborersix came also but Mobi was the only one to give sahayog. When our Rawal sister [Bishnu] came to return the labor, she helped us cut and haul wheat home. Bishnu helped us for nine days since we had to cut and store the wheat quickly before livestock or animals come to eat the wheat. Wild cats (syãro) are especially likely to invade our fields. At that time we also called our older and younger brother and one younger sister. Altogether five people came to give sahayog with the wheat. The act of gift exchange closely approaches an ideal of equal exchange, but if we start with the premise that partners with different constituents of capital bargain for slightly different amounts in the exchange process, then even labor gifts in Jãjarkoë can be unequal labor exchanges. In the above case Mobi gave four days and Bishnu exchanged in return nine days, even given the caveat of the speaker that the work ‘had to be done quickly’ which implied workers necessarily had to work nine days until all grain was gathered and stored. The Thãkuri household either owes five days’ labor to the Rawals or they received more labor due to their caste and class position above the Rawals. The Rawal family will in turn ask for some favor, thereby renewing the cycle of gifts and counter gifts. The timing and nature of the counter gift will be contingent upon each households’ forms of value, including caste and class social status. In this case the Thakur 306 partner has higher caste status, which might explain why the Rawals donated more labor days. Each partner brings different constituent amounts and forms of capital into the trade. Essentially any form of value which partners legitimate, objectify, and barter constitutes volume of capital. Finally, I heard of a 'congealed labor' form of sahayog: gifts of money. Well educated salaried men in the District Center occasionally told me that money can be an appropriate form of sahayog. I can imagine that households which are employed in a government job have less time to donate labor as help. As Ganesh Bikram, an accountant at the Nepal Bank Limited, explained, My favorite special celebrations - Desain, Tihar, Sakrãnti, Holi, Shiva Ratri, Puspundra gate, and Saltamanx - all require that we buy special worship (pujã) articles. If someone cannot find the money for tika powder, candles, banana, incense, or the other things, I can give them these things or money for these things. This too is sahayog. The range of meanings open to people who employ sahayog develops and changes as their circumstances change. The farmer gifts agricultural labor, the teacher gifts knowledge, the neighbor gifts money and wedding preparations. For partners of unequal social status sahayog becomes merely a polite euphemism. The political aspirant gives favors to his patron and the unskilled agricultural worker gives labor for a return of food and wages. Sahayog gives households an opportunity to interact with their neighbors, creating closer social ties, while at the same time fulfilling the everyday requirements of production. Sahayog presents a form of efficient management of a few laborers with flexibility of hours. Sahayog eases hierarchical caste tensions and reduces the stress of paternalism. Quantitative perspectives of Egalitarian Exchange Far from being merely social gestures of neighborly friendship, parimã, sahayog, baure represent an important contribution to agricultural production. Since the region is 307 overwhelmingly labor intensive rather than capital intensive, I argue that even small amounts of labor days when applied at precise work periods, can greatly increase efficiency of agricultural production. I present a close accounting of labor days received by a sample of twelve households in one village, Somdãda. I conclude that the intake of approximately thirty-seven labor days per year per household (which participates) in labor exchange represents a fundamentally capitalfree productive relationship. I present information on two types of households in the second half of this section. Parimã-user households (N=96) are compared with households which do not use parimã (N = 24) based on the Peripheral Region Survey (PRS; N=120). Like the conclusions from the small sample in Somdãda village, parimã-user households in the PRS have a certain set of socioeconomic conditions which are different from households which do not use reciprocal labor exchanges. Broadly, households which use labor exchange regularly are depicted in the survey as 1) having larger average household size; 2) owning medium amounts of land (5-20 ropani); 3) owning much more livestock than households which do not use labor exchange; 4) growing more vegetable varieties than other households; 5) using certain loan forms more often than other households (shop credit, interest bearing loans, and grain loans); 6) able to sell and barter more farm goods than other households; 7) more likely to hire laborers and rent land than other households; and finally parimã users 8) are more likely to use certain development opportunities (veterinary, forestry office, family planning, agriculture office, agricultural development bank) than households which do not use labor exchange. In terms of a social class, the parimã user households, 82% of the PRS sample, are drawn largely from 'Owner-with-Tenant', 'Owner-Cultivator', and 'Laborer-Cultivator' social classes. The 'Landlord' and 'Landless' social classes do not meet the criteria which are necessary for efficient use of labor exchange in agriculture. 308 Labor reciprocity in Somdãda Village In northern rural Jãjarkoë most households use parimã or sahayog. A village of 130 households, Somdãda is no exception. The village is composed of Magar households with a handful of Gurung, Kami and Sãrki households. Located at 2100 to 2700 meters, most smallholders grow corn, taro, potatoes, and dryland rice. There are few surplus crops or businesses. Two families sell basic goods like cigarettes, candles, dhup, and ëikãs out of their homes. Subsistence and enough grain for the household's needs is the goal of production. In Somdãda village nine of the thirteen households I surveyed used egalitarian labor exchange.xi Two land-poor and two land-rich households did not use parimã, sahayog, or baure. The parimã-user households (N=9) remembered asking for an average of 37.3 labor days in the last year from their neighbors. Tables 7.1 and 7.2 present information on Labor Recruitment in Somdãda. The Tables primarily show agricultural tasks for which labor is recruited, labor days received, and land/household consumption size. 309 Table 7.1 Labor Received in Somdãda (N = 13 households) Action Set Stems (dalnu) Prepare Soil/ Plant Weed Carry Fertilizer Harvest General Crop # Laborers Received Corn Corn Corn Corn 3 2 2 1 3 8 15 1 Corn Rice Rice Corn Corn Corn Corn Millet Barley Corn & Potato 1 4 1 1 1 1 3 2 3 4 3 6 6 5 6 3 3 4 Parimã Baure Parimã Parimã Sahayog Parimã Baure Parimã Parimã 1 2 9 9 8 9 10 3 3 8 Baure 12 -Corn Corn Wheat Wheat Millet Rice Rice - 3 1 2 5 3 3 1 1 5 3 #Labor Name of Days Exchange H.H. # Received 12 4 20 4 5 2 1 2 10 Parimã Parimã Baure Parimã Parimã Parimã Baure Parimã Sahayog Parimã Parimã Sahayog "Kãm gardna joun" 3 6 7 8 9 1 9 1 3 1 1 3 12 Total labor days: 336 Average Number days/year agricultural labor Received: 37.3 (336/9 h.h. which use labor exchange) *Kãm gardnã joun refers to communal labor ("Let's go work!) 310 Table 7.2 Labor Days per Household in Somdãda H.H. = household Received Landholding H.H. Consumption H.H. # Labor days (Muri) sizexii 1 27 17 4 2 12 22.2 3.25 3 52 9 4 4 0 8.4 4.5 5 0 5 5 6 16 23 4.5 7 30 22 4.5 8 6 8 3.25 9 130 24.5 2.5 10 9 13 3.25 11 0 74 8.5 12 3 15 7.75 13 0 50 10 Total Labor Days = 336; Total labor days received /h.h. = 37.3 Labor Exchange Users (N = 9) average landholding 17.1 rop. Non-User Households (N = 4) average landholding 34.4 rop. Households often receive a mixture of parimã, sahayog, and baure. Combined, these labor practices represent an important contribution to agricultural production. Households in Somdãda received help from other households at least one month out of twelve or about 37 days per year. Since labor received is reciprocal, approximately the same amount of labor is again given out to neighboring households. This implies that households with small to medium size landholdings work in reciprocal labor for up to 70 days per year. Owning no land means the family cannot participate in parimã while more than 50 ropani (2.5 hectare) implies that the family will hire workers or sublet land. The labor reciprocity activities of one village do not, however, create an informed quantitative depiction of the role of parimã. In the following section I use information from 120 households to create a profile of those households which regularly use parimã and those which do not participate in labor exchange activities. 311 Labor Reciprocity among Peripheral Region Survey Households In the following Figures I present a profile of households which regularly use parimã versus those households which do not. I compare profiles of parimã Users versus Non-Users with information on 1) land and livestock; 2) loans; 3) Trading; 4) Labor practices; and 5) Development related activities. After presenting Figures 7.5-7.9, I comment on differences between parimã Users and other households. Figure 7.5 Household, Land, and Livestock of Parimã Users versus Non-Users Characteristic Parima User (N= 96) Non-User (N= 24) Average household size 7.7 6.8 Average landholding (Ropani) 11.5 12 Average # livestock 15.4 6.25 16 13 Average # vegetable types Receives Collateral loan Gives Simple loan Receives Simple loan Receives Shop credit Gives loan w/ interest Parima User (N= 96) Gives grain loans Non-User (N= 24) Receives loans w/ interest 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Gives Collateral loan Figure 7.6 Lending Patterns of Parimã Users versus Non-Users % of Surveys Receives grain loans 312 313 Figure 7.7 Trading Preferences of Parimã Users Versus Non-Users % of Surveys 80 70 Parima User 60 Non-User 50 40 30 20 10 Sells fruit/veges Sells Dairy Sells grains Barters Wheat Barters Rice Barters Corn Barters Potato 0 Figure 7.8 Labor practices of Parimã Users Versus Non-Users 100 90 Parima User Non-User 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 Hires Labor Labors for Others Receives Adhiya Gives Adhiya Receives Khalo 0 Gives Khalo % of Surveys 80 314 Figure 7.9 Development related activities of Parimã Users Versus Non-Users 80 70 Parima User 60 % of Surveys Non-User 50 40 30 20 10 Participated in politics Visited Nepal Bank Ltd Visited Ag'l Dev. Bank Visited Agriculture Off. Visited Family Plan. Off. Visited Forestry Office Visited veternary Visited hospital Has Irrigation Lives near water tap 0 In Figure 7.5 one sees that household sizes between parimã User households and parimã Non-user households are roughly equal, or that parimã User households have slightly larger families. With slightly smaller average land holdings, parimã User households still own much more livestock and grow several more varieties of vegetables than parimã Non-user households. Figure 7.5 does not show, however, the social class or wealth of households in the parimã User households versus the parimã Non-user households. By looking at parimã Nonuser households individually and in histograms (not shown), I noticed that many poor and a few wealthy households fell into the parimã Non-user household category. Thus parimã Non-user households' average household size, land, etc. is split between near landless and land-rich 315 households which have over 50 ropani of land. Landholdings for the parimã User households however are much more concentrated in the .5-1 hectare range. The parimã User households represent the 82% of households (N = 96/120) which are neither landless, nor one of the few village elite households with many resources and wealth. A Pearson Product Moment correlation using two separate groups can help display the meaningful relationships among parimã User households and the lack of significance among some characteristics of the parimã Non-user households. Table 7.3 Pearson Product Moment Correlations Set A Parimã User Households (N= 96) versus parimã Non-User Households (N=24) x = correlation performed on two variables; h.h. = household Correlation Categories h.h.=household 1. h.h. size x Land Holding Size 2. h.h. size x Landlord 3. h.h. size x h.h. taking shop credit 4. Land size x Users of Nepal Bank 5. Tenants x h.h. taking shop credit 6. Tenants x h.h. taking grain loans 7. Tenants x Employers 8. Laborer x owns irrigation 9. Laborer x # livestock owned Parimã User h.h. .27 -.18 .14 .20 .24 .26 -.22 -.14 -.24 Parimã Non-User h.h. -.07 .04 .00 .04 .03 -.09 -.03 -.09 .03 The correlations indicate the following assertions about parimã user households: 1) parimã users have larger households as their landholdings increase; 2) the larger families tend not to be landlords; 3) larger families tend to take shop credit; 4) larger landowners tend to use the Nepal Bank limited; 5) tenants tend to take shop credit also; 6) tenants tend to take grain loans; 7) families that rent land tend not to employ workers; 8) families who do labor tend not to own irrigated lands; and 9) laborers tend to own less livestock. Non-user households however, do not correlate on any of the above criteria. This is because the composition of households which do not do parimã is split between large landlords and landless laborers. Given the actual compositions of parimã User households and the 316 parimã Non-user households , one should read the averages in Figures 7.5 -7.9 as accurate portrayals for the parimã user households but questionable for the parimã Non- user households. Figure 7.6 profiles lending practices of parimã user households and other households. One sees that parimã user households commonly give simple no-interest loans (sapat). They are very willing to take shop credit (udãro) and about 25% of parimã user households lend credit with interest (paisa byãj ko riÿ) and grain loans (anãj ko riÿ) which have very high interest rates of 33% per annum. Parimã Non-user households have lower averages for use of shop credit, interest loans, and grain loans possibly because they haven't grain to trade or money for interest loans. A few of the Parimã Non-user households however, the large landlords, do have rice to sell. Parimã Non-user households, especially the near landless, use collateral loans (bandhãk). These loans involve movable and immovable property as collateral (dhito) rather than cash for low income households. Checking the significance of parimã User households versus parimã Non-user households, the statistical correlations do show that lending patterns usually mimic availability of resources regardless of whether the family uses parimã or not. For example, in both groups, the following lending correlations were significant: Table 7.4 Pearson Product Moment Correlations Set B Parimã User households (N= 96) versus parimã Non-user households (N=24) x = correlation of variables; h.h. = household Correlation Categories Parimã User h.h. 1. Landlord x h.h. gives collateral loans 2. Landlord x h.h. gives simple loans 3. Landlord x h.h. takes interest loans 4. Tenant x takes collateral loans 5. Laborer x uses Ag.l Dev. Bank 6. Employer x uses Nepal Bank .22 .32 .22 .24 -.11 .37 Parimã Non-User h.h. .29 .19 -.19 -.16 -.20 .41 317 For both groups the following statements hold: 1) landlords tend to give collateral loans (bandhãk); landlords tend to give simple loans (sapat); laborers tend to not use the Agricultural Development Bank, while employers tend to use the Nepal Bank Limited. The parimã and Non-user groups are split however on the use of interest bearing loans by landlords and collateral loans by tenants. A tentative explanation my be that the parimã Non-users, made up of large landlords and near landless households, may not take interest or collateral loans because these loans do not fit their economic needs. From Figure 7.7 one sees that parimã User households prefer to barter grains and sell dairy, fruits and vegetables more often than other households. These households are involved in agricultural production more than parimã Non-user households. Sale (not barter) of rice was the only area in which parimã Non-user households excelled. Perhaps, large landlords sell excess grain to their neighbors. Landless artisans receive nearly all their payments for services (khal) in grain yet they never reported selling surplus grain. Medium sized landowners which do parimã are inclined to store excess grain for drought seasons. Jãjarkoë is a grain deficit region and the Nepal Food Corporation imports rice. The sale of dairy products was notably controlled by parimã User households. Livestock production implies calling on neighbors to take turns watching the livestock shelters (goëh). Parimã Non-user households do not have livestock if they are poor or if they are large landlords subletting land. Figure 7.8 suggests that parimã User households are more often high caste and tend to both hire laborers and rent land more often than parimã Non-user households. In fact, 85% of households which do parimã are high caste versus 75% of the parimã Non-user households. The typical parimã User household needs access to more land and laborers than parimã Nonuser households. Finally, In Figure 7.9 one sees that parimã user households oriented toward agricultural development opportunities more than parimã Non- user households. Parimã user households build irrigation channels (31%), visit the Forestry Office (20%), Agricultural Development 318 Office (25%), and Agricultural Development Bank (19%) more often than parimã Non- user households. Since parimã Non- user households are split between large landlords and small near landless households, over 70% of these households live near village centers and working water taps. This survey population may be more inclined to sample hospital care (71%) in addition to traditional healers. Given their increased reliance on wages and money, they tend to use the Nepal Bank Limited (29%) more than parimã user households (17%). Overall, parimã user households represent the large stable middle classes in Jãjarkoë. These households are oriented toward agricultural production for their own subsistence with a small surplus for trade. These households are dependent on livestock production and actively recruit relatives and neighbors for rotating shepherding in the forested ridges above their villages. They generally are not inclined to use development services as evidenced by low rates of visits to veterinary, forestry, and agriculture offices. Conclusion: A question of equality and reciprocity In this chapter I have outlined three main points. First, reciprocal labor practices are fluid; they overlap definitionally. Recall that the Karki family, in their rice transplanting day, combined adhiyå, parimã, sahayog, and baure. Sometimes local people say that there is no difference between parimã and sahayog; sometimes they say there is no difference between baure and jãla. From an emic point of view these labor practices may share many similarities in practice yet they do have distinct meaning. The second main point I have stressed is that reciprocal labor practices do not overlap in some ways; this is why they have distinct names and rules of practice. Witness a farmer decision-making tree: Figure 7.10 Decision-Making Tree for Parimã Use 319 Will my extended network of relatives or my neighbors be willing to d parima? Yes !!! !!no - reject parima Will we have enough time to do the work? Yes !!!!!no - reject parima Will I have enough land to effectively employ a dozen or more people Yes !!!!!no - reject parima Do we have more grain or money resources? grain !!!! favor parima !!!money favor other labor Thus if parima does not work for one of the above reasons, another practice may be employed, such as baure (called daily labor). The third point I made in this chapter is that negotiated exchange takes place. Sometimes an exchange is called “equal” when in fact it is not equal at all. The exchange of labor is often tilted in favor of the household with more wealth or resources. Households amass their total resources - symbolic, political, cultural, and economic - when they negotiate labor exchanges. If the households continue their labor exchange relationship this causes an unequal 320 exchange relationship to build over time, a feature of paternalism. When high and low castes interact, generally the low caste has to give more labor or resources in what may be called negative reciprocity or unequal exchange. Yet low caste households occasionally successfully negotiate a superior exchange with households of higher status. In conclusion, it seems that the households which use reciprococity tend to be medium size households with larger than average livestock holdings who live in more rural settings than the District Capital. These households do not have too much land and are able to negotiate labor exchanges with neighbors who also have medium amounts of household labor and land. These households rely on traditional lending forms, they do not rely on development services in the Capital, they tend to barter their grains with their neighbors and sell excess dairy products. They are important members of the community in that they get involved in political processes more frequently than other households. Such households use a maximum amount of outside labor and will hire workers (using baure) when exchanges cannot be negotiated. I think it is particularly important to keep in mind that these types of households represent the stereotype of Nepali farming families. Parima and sahayog thus represent very important central processes in agricultural production. Unfortunately, these labor practices are not well recognized by researchers as core management systems. Any understanding of Nepalese agropastoralism and agriculture should in the future acknowledge the central role of labor reciprocity, taking these into account when small scale farming development schemes are implemented. In the next chapter, the everyday presentation of social hierarchy is explored using little signifiers like words and clothing. How is hierarchy negotiated? How is it represented? How does one signify labor practice and one's productive role in a social hierarchy? N otes to Chapter Seven 321 iIn literature of labor exchange there are several analogous terms close to the meaning of "cooperation and exploitation." The terms "symmetry" and "asymmetry" (Campbell n.d.) and "equal and unequal" (Emmanual 1972) contains many semantic similarities. The set of terms "egalitarian and equal" versus "hierarchical and ranked" has been used in literature of jajmãni relationships. I use cooperation and exploitation since these refer directly to labor exchanges of cooperation or exploitation. ii The Karkis own land which yields about 30 muris rice, 8 muris wheat, 25 muris barley, and 35 muris corn. For comparison, one hectare yields approximately 78 muri grain. One muri equals about 91 liters or about 62 kilograms. The Karkis also own about four cow, two oxen, one buffalo, six goats, six chickens, 1 sheep, and a rabbit. Their main home is located near their khet land and they have another five homes in the District Center. The family consists of father, mother, two sons, two daughters, two daughters-in-law, several grandchildren. One son and one daughter do government office work. The parents continue to farm a little but spend much time in the District Capital with children and grandchildren. Most farming is done by tenants. iii iv v /hal*/ may be an Indo-European cognate of the etymologically difficult to trace /har*/ > harrow. In parimã the final vowel was pronounced as / √ /, a lower back vowel similar to the English "but", though back in the mouth, as in "boat". The Jumli and Dolpi herders come down into the area in winter looking for edible trade items. Any extra grains, clarified butter, and vegetable oil can be sold by Jãjarkoëis without going to a distant market. Most households sell less than twenty-five dollars worth of agricultural surplus but still the extra cash is important for household budgets. vi There is a Nepalese variation of Hindu caste laws on food restriction: high castes won’t give low castes pure foods. High castes believe that their buffalo will dry up if they give milk and curd to low castes. I heard this many times as an explanation why high castes won't feed low castes dairy products. vii When Nepali speakers invoke bikãs or it's adjective, bikãsi, they may imply many things. General semantic features of bikãs include 'new', 'modern,' and 'developed’ or even ‘foreign.' viii ix x Jaiselu healers deal mainly with malevolent spirits and witches. ‘Called labor’ or 'casual labor' (baure) can be called jãla (daily labor) though some people felt there was a distinction. Desain is in October Tihar is 'Brother Worship' in later october Sakranti is first day of new moon in each month Holi is full moon in february (phagun) Siva Ratri-'night of Siva' to celebrate the god Siva 322 Puspundra gaté is a celebration which boys and girls especially like, on the fifteenth day of the moon in the month of Push Saltaman is a name for New Year's in April of the Bikram Samvat calendar. xi For parameters of Rural Region Surveys see Appendix. I surveyed seven rural villages over one day's walk from the District Center. In each I chose 10% of the households in the village and took representative households from across caste and class lines. With my village host I count the households, determine their caste and relative wealth. I then choose 10% of each type of caste and class (high, medium, low) represented. xii See Chapter Five Footnote 10 for estimation of consumption size of households. 327 8 THE CULTURAL CONSTRUCTION OF LABOR What it means to be a sharecropper, landlord, or bonded laborer is bound up with the political and historical circumstances of a particular place and time. A sharecropper in the United States has a decidedly different lived experience than a sharecropper in Jãjarkoë, for example. In this chapter, I present three texts which convey some of the cultural meanings attached to being a landlord, an artisan, and a sharecropping tenant in Jãjarkoë. By presenting texts of subjective human experiences, I hope to convey a sense of what possession of high or low caste status implies in Jãjarkoë and of what it means to be classed as a worker versus an owner of property. In this chapter I examine one legend and two conversations in which asymmetrical labor relations are symbolized, negotiated, and resisted. I see cultural expressions such as storytelling, legends, and late night gossip as ways in which people actively negotiate, resist, and use rhetoric in order to influence their relative social positions. In a sense, householders gather their "capital" for negotiation using cultural, symbolic, economic, and political resources (Bourdieu 1987). Words become the signs which signify and even shape realities, as in the utterance "She was a landowner and owned many livestock." By these words, a social position of ownership of property and by inference of good political standing has been signified. In Jãjarkoëi society, almost all men and women are orally literate but do not read and write. In this circumstance, dependency on oral literacy implies that utterances, especially formalized ones such as sayings, legends, word games, and mantars (religious utterances), have tremendous significance (Maskarinec 1990b). It is especially such utterances which lend concreteness to the material realities of land ownership and social status. Language use is not an open field of competition and communication, however. Throughout this chapter, I stress that language and non-verbal actions are controlled by the interests of more powerful segments of the society (Hymes 1973). It is not language per se 328 which oppresses laborers, artisans, and low castes, but the way in which the elite of the society construct and dictate how language is used. As J. Mey noted, "language cements the dominant interests of our society, helping to oppress a large segment of the population (1985:16).” Similarly, Jãjarkoë speakers use language and non-verbal communications to shape their social positions as landlords, tenants, patrons, artisans, employers, and laborers. In Jãjarkoë the views of Bãhuns, landed elite, and royalty primarily shape official discourse and opinion about appropriate social relations. The views put forth by workers such as tailors, firewood collectors, and house builders often form a counter-hegemony which balances elite proscriptions. Linguistic stylistic devices abundantly convey meaning and the social position of speaker and referents. In addition to quotable utterances, verb choice, lexicon, prosodic features (such as vowel lengthening), speech registers, and non-verbal cues (such as winks, bent fingers, jeering, and styles of greetings) abundantly convey a speaker's beliefs about the social and labor status of the subjects under discussion. Further, utterances usually involve metacommunication, a more complex discourse which incorporates underlying assumptions about proper social relationships, religious beliefs, commentaries about whole classes of people, and even unconscious attitudes (Babcock 1984). In deconstructing the cultural meanings attached to labor relationships, I focus on verbal utterances which are most easily translated into English, but I also include selected information on metacommunication, non-verbal signals, and prosodic features. The actual cultural construction of labor is multifaceted. In this chapter I present symbols and utterances which signify the cultural construction of relationships involving the asymmetry of resources such as land. I highlight conflicts involving landlords/tenants because much of my dissertation situates labor relations within patronage and sharecropping, and the unequal exchange process. There certainly do exist conflicts over resources in more egalitarian labor relationships (such as parimã, simple labor exchange, or sahayog, gifts of labor), but 329 given the limits of a chapter format, I shall explicate examples involving obvious asymmetry of work relations. The opening case is a legend of land asseveration. The landowner, a Bãhun widow, is harassed by a land-grabbing naiki, a royal functionary who supposedly protects forests and people. The widow solves the conflict using supernatural retribution. This legend was told to me by a landowner, and his metanarrative commentary implied that one should not steal the land of their neighbors lest they meet with divine retribution. The legend both teaches and counters hegemonic beliefs about land and social position. The legend is unusual in its attention to the force of a woman's will and their power to use sati to destroy enemies rather than simply worship husband and family. The second example of the cultural expression of productive relations introduces Gogane Rawot, a centenarian fisherman and ferryman. Through a conversation with Goganeji, I explicate how local labor practices constitute a highly efficient, though exploitative, management of small scale production. The centenarian's experiences highlight the interdependence of patronage, sharecropping, and casual labor. His viewpoint also highlights a value orientation which stresses egalitarianism and social symmetry though he does not achieve this sort of relationship with his elite masters. For Gogane, hierarchy, ritual purity and pollution are to be minimized in everyday discourse while egalitarianism, fairness, and cooperation are ethics to be stressed in work relationships. In a third example, a registered tenant (mohi) and goldsmith, Bhãrat Sunãr, describes both his fealty to nobility and resistance to domination. His renderings are discursive memories of land asseveration and the surrounding legal and mythical circumstances. Bhãratji emphasizes his good relationships with one set of elites and at the same time he denigrates another set of elites who tried to exploit his family. It is a mistake, I argue, to imagine a monolithic cultural construct of common peasants resisting or patronizing elite peasants (Scott 1976). 330 This chapter is also guided by feminist analyses of the cultural construction of gender (Ortner 1974; Goodale 1980). As H. Moore has pointed out (1988:13), feminist anthropologists have contributed a sustained analysis of the symbols and sexual stereotypes of gender, and have observed an enormous variation in the cultural meaning of the categories of 'man' and 'woman'. In a similar manner, the cultural construction of those persons who give labor consistently (workers, artisans, laborers) and those who take labor (employers, landlords) are deeply rooted in religious ideologies and symbolic features. The categories of 'labor giver' and 'labor receiver' are interesting in that, unlike gender, they may shift onto and off of a person. A person may be marked as [+laborer] or [-laborer] under different conditions. Many people, such as full time crafts specialists, almost all low castes, and landless migrants continually are marked symbolically as [+laborer]. On the other end of the productive continuum, people who are large landowners and landlords in Jãjarkoë semantically are marked [-laborer]. As a guide to understanding the symbolic dichotomy of labor giver and labor taker, one might stereotype these semantic fields through a structuralist set of categories. 331 Table 8.1 Semantic Features of Ideal Labor Giver versus Labor Taker Labor Giver abikãsi (undeveloped) backward chadaïi giver dependent dirty down forested honest (sojo) illiterate impure (juëho) inferior landless left low mundane natural passive polluting poor prãkriti service simple subsistence thin (dublo) weak Labor Taker bikãsi (developed) forward benefactor independent clean up cultivated clever (chalaki) literate pure (chokho) superior landed right high sacred cultured active clean wealthy sãnskriti patron complex surplus healthy (moëo) strong While these ideal characteristics signify workers, their character, and their relationships with their patrons, bear in mind that these semantic tags do not imply that the bearer is poor, polluting, or simple. These semantic features are merely an initial symbolic entry into understanding the many complex meanings which go into the construction of asymmetrical labor relations in Jãjarkoë. Many labor givers are also labor receivers at other points in time; for example, a patron who receives help from his or her neighbors during harvest time using parimã may later be the labor giver. The complex of semantic features does not apply permanently to the parimã participant in this case. But an artisan, who is by definition low caste, will carry the semantic features of a labor giver in a very intrinsic and subjective sense of selfhood. 332 These dualisms of /worker : owner/ are not the complete set of possible semantic features in Nepali ideology, nor are they a complete set of possible social descriptions of workers. For example, one common dualism which does not apply is that of earth : seed :: female : male as is common in other cultural contexts. Labor givers are not any more associated with females or the earth than are labor receivers. Secondly, there exist important work ideals for householders in Jãjarkoë which are applied to both workers and owners such as being "not lazy" (alchhi lagdainan) and being cooperative or harmonious with others (milaune i mãnchhe). The list above is meant as a heuristic device for interpreting the following textual materials and the symbolic realms of workers and owners in Jãjarkoë. As a proviso to this chapter, I emphasize that there are no stereotypical bounded vignettes of cultural meanings attached to work relations. There are only the snatches of words which we excerpt from the flow of reality. I have selected these examples of labor relations since, for myself, they ordered the cultural realities of unequal labor relations. In essence, they are renderings of renderings which others presented to me. I hope they will also inform the reader of the subtle cues which create and maintain inequality in labor relations. Chatur Malla: A Legendary Landowner (and Wrathful Spirit) Ideology refers generally to superstructural aspects of production and more concretely to art, language, costuming, academic hierarchies, religious rites, and symbolically filled practices. The concept "ideology" is used in several related but different senses. R. Williams articulates three distinct uses of "ideology": 1. A system of beliefs characteristic of a particular class or group; 2. A system of illusory beliefs - false ideas or consciousness - which can be contrasted with true or scientific knowledge; and 3. The general process of the production of meaning and ideas. (1977: 55) 333 All of these glosses are important to understanding the role of ideology in determining structure although the first meaning contains a distinct hegemonizing character. The influence of a dominant class over subordinate ones is accomplished by the naturalization of particular ideologies relating to concepts of work, self esteem, and power. R. Barthes points out that a function of myth is to naturalize the relationship of signifier to signified, a relation which actually is originally arbitrary, since language is defined by its "arbitrariness of the sign to its grounding." But myths "resort to a false nature...which decorate their usefulness with a natural appearance" (1972 (1957): 126f). There is a subterfuge which myth exhibits in its distortions of truth. Myths, and the underlying ideologies, make people act regardless of facts which may be contrary to objective circumstance. Social myths motivate people to enact piety, religious belief, ethnocentrisms, discrimination, or elitism even when these fly in the face of objective circumstance. Myths are hegemonic in their naturalization of social rules and relationships. Social myths occasionally counter the prevailing dominant ideologies and when these confrontational myths occur, a counter-hegemonic discourse develops. These myths, created by suppressed or exploited groups, invariably use conflict as a main theme. In Jãjarkoë weaker partners in labor relationships -- artisans, sharecroppers, daily laborers -- characteristically resent their positions; they seek the best terms they can obtain in labor relationships and they often complain through gossip, story, and myth. An example of a subversive legend which was told to me in Jãjarkoë is that of the founding of Malikã Mandir about twenty minutes' walk west of Jãjarkoë's district capital. In some facets, the legend of Chatur Malla resists traditional precepts of women's subordinate position in a family. Yet in that the protagonist hails from a Brãhmanical background the legend yields to Hindu dictates of proper Brãhmanical duty. I recount the story below as told to me by Y. Karki (Journal 1:77-79, 1987). For translation purposes I have used some English folk story verbal style markers, such as "Once..." (indefinite past) and quotation markers to signal a character's utterances. In Nepali the speaker used Nepali folk story techniques such as indirect speech, marked by the verbal post-position "- 334 re" as in Rãjã aibaksincha-re meaning 'the king comes [according to news that the speaker has heard].' Nepali indirect speech is cumbersome to translate into English as is the royal verb form -baksinu. Karkiji also used simple Nepali rather than complex narration techniques since I had been in Jãjarkoë for only four months at the time of the storytelling; there are probably more elaborate versions of this legend. Karkiji told the tale after I had come back from spending full moon (purni) at the popular picnic spot and shrine of Malikã Mandir. Families typically enjoy camping during purni at this spot which is located about 900 meters above and west of the District Capital. The Legend of Chatur Malla There once were two Rãjãs, the King of Jãjarkoë and a small ruler who lived four hours west of here in Khalaÿgã. He was a naiki (the leader of any political group; a pradhãn or mukhiyã). Chatur Malla was a Brahmin widow who lived with her father-in-law. She lived only with her fatherin-law, his servant and her own servant who worked their fields which were very fertile. The small ruler (naiki) wanted her field and he asked for it. But they didn't give it to him. The small ruler became angry and he took the field and the following season plowed and planted rice. Chatur Malla was helpless to fight against the little ruler. One day she talked with her father-in-law about their stolen field. She told her fatherin-law, "I will commit sati." She will burn herself in the fire. Her fatherin-law asked, "But why would you do such a thing, my daughter?." She said, "I will give sãno Rãjã [the small king; the naiki] my möë ãëmã, my dead spirit. My spirit will cause him terrible harm and pain and he will lose his family and wealth. He will be lost after I die." They then planned this thing. In the field she put stacks and stacks of wood. She then started it, sat upon it, and was consumed. Before she committed sati her father-in-law said, "We will bring the case before the great King of Jãjarkoë. He will decide. If we lose, well, then you can commit ãtmãhatyã [killing the soul]. The Father-inlaw went to Jãjarkoë to have the case decided. "If the case is decided 335 against us I will play the sankar [conch]." he said. He played the sanch ii [also conch]. From that day her spirit went to the sãno raja’s home. And much harm came to him. He lost cows, buffaloes, family, his mother, brother, and son. The advisor of the small ruler consulted with him. He told the little king that he did a wrong deed. "You took the field from Chatur Malla and her spirit is causing you harm." So the little king built a temple to her, sacrificed a goat, and prayed [bajyo] to Chatur Malla. After a long time, she left him and gave him peace. (Karkiji concluded,) In this area [a hilltop west of Jãjarkoë where stands a small shrine. The area is called Malikã] if a powerful man does potential harm to a weak man, the weak man goes to the temple and prays to Chatur Malla. This will help him. She will hurt the amuk or powerful man by causing him pain. This myth is unusual and indicative of certain labor relations in three respects. First, the passive role of the King of Jãjarkoë connotes a sense of tolerance for other forms of political power and a lack of real jurisdiction in rural politics. The fact that the King never speaks or acts but is still symbolically the regional ruler supports the idea that segmentary rule is common. With segmentary rule ritual suzerainty is accorded a noble figure while actual political power is distributed to regional figures (Stein 1980; Southall n.d.). This indeed is the case historically in Jãjarkoë, which was one of the baisi Rãjã, the "twenty-two kingdoms" of western Nepal. Second, that a powerless character confronts and gains revenge over a powerful character is unusual. In many myths concerning Nepalese political relations, either a powerless character aligns with a powerful character [story of the "The clever orphan"], or a moral powerful character is confronted by a corrupt powerful character [story of "Prithivi Narayan Shah confronts Indian Rãjã"]. Often local proverbs depict a powerless character overcome by 336 circumstances outside his/her control. The saying, garibko dãu, kabai naau; garibko mouka kahilo ãudainã "A poor person never gets a chance," highlights the frequent futility of justice for the impoverished. Third, although theoretical considerations of sati abound in India (see for example, A. Nandy 1975; L. Mani 1990; A. Yang 1989), these are not linked to revenge. Discussions of immolation uniformly view sati as powerfully beneficial for the religious merit of husband and wife. As Mani notes, the widow "...is consistently portrayed as either a heroine - entering the raging flames of the pyre with no display of emotion - or an abject victim - thrown upon the heap, sometimes fastened to it by the unscrupulous family members or pundits. (1990:117)" Yet Chatur Malla employs sati as revenge, a specific and self calculated means of resistance. Chatur Malla is no passive girl-child as are depictions of Indian widows. Note that Nepali stereotypical renditions of sati do not entreat widows to join the funeral pyre of husband. Nepali widows, if ever they would commit sati, are enjoined to 'get their worldly affairs in order' before committing themselves to immolation. This includes seeing children through their education, repayment of debts, etc. The actual act of sati may take place as much as twenty years after the death of a husband (J. Thompson, personal communication). Chatur Malla uses immolation but Karkiji also calls her action "soul killing" (ãtmãhatyã; suicide), a violent physical act of resistance, to gain revenge. The legend connotes a realistic sense of the utter loss of property and feelings of destitute helplessness. Chatur Malla's last recourse was to kill herself and haunt the petty Rãjã with her soul not yet ready to iii depart for the next life. The myth portrays the farmers as vengeful, resorting to supernatural justice. Chatur Malla's action warns power mongers and land grabbers that their greed will bring them not only ill-gotten land but destruction and death. While the legend is counter-hegemonic in its use of immolation as revenge, still it follows precepts of Hindu morality. Chatur Malla's example upholds the ideology that Bãhun widows should practice self immolation for the sake of their family's honor. The family was 337 violated by the Raja’s seizure of their property. Since the greater Rãjã did not protect their interests, the Bãhun widow and her father-in-law relied on sacred Hindu strictures to right the transgression. The legend notably depicts the Bãhun woman as a widow. If she were married with a husband still alive, it would have been inappropriate for her to use suicide for revenge. Instead, her husband should have begun a land dispute by bringing a claim against the naiki. The myth is also notable in that a female instigates a powerful action. Powerful iv females were present in myths I heard, yet never was the word shakti used. The Bãhun widow's power might have come less from Hindu tradition than from a local ideology of females as powerful. Note that local female deities -- such as the Maäëã sisters, a set of about nine rather competitive women -- perform such inverted activities as hunting large game, killing their father whom they mistake for a large animal, and fighting with each other over rights to ruling powers (Maskarinec 1990a). There are several power players in the legend and they all have material interests in conflict at times: the greater king, the naiki (local Rãjã), the Bãhun father-in-law, and Chatur Malla herself. The legend aptly portrays the interplay of various interests in land and political power. Myths ."..reveal the heterogeneous systems that resist the formation of a unitary base of truth (Saldívar, 1990: 207).” Narratives such as Chatur Malla "fight back," and resist the hegemonizing nature of dominant discourses. If Chatur Malla had simply allowed the naiki to take her land, there would be no shrine on the hilltop near the District Center and no legend to commemorate her. Chatur Malla's servants were mentioned, but they are quite tangential to the story; they provide support to the social position of the Bãhun family. Since the myth is about suicide as a weapon of vengeance, a servant's self immolation would be ineffective; the servant is believed to be truly powerless. If a low caste person commits suicide, it would not be for preservation of family honor. To preserve family land or honor, low castes use patrons and law courts to defend property. 338 Finally, this myth can be seen as a form of discourse by the dominant elite, and therefore not a counter hegemony at all. If a commoner hears this myth, s/he may not think of the moral given in the story at all (weak persons can propitiate Chatur Malla if they've been wronged). A more stark meaning either consciously or unconsciously put forth by Karkiji might be, "If you attempt to seize land illegally, a terrible wrath of supernatural beings will descend upon you." Often parables are have multiple meanings (Narayan 1989). Even a commoner planning to snip off a bit of his relative's land may be warned about Chatur Malla and what happened when her land was snatched. A subtle self reference does come from Karkiji. Karkiji is in many ways in a similar position to Chatur Malla in terms of landlord status. He can not walk to his land holdings because the route is hilly and takes two full walking days to reach his natal village. In a journal entry, I dubbed my last visit there "Crawling to Karkigaun" because we actually had to use our hands to scramble up the last 600 meters to the village. Perforce, illegal tenants have settled on his land. Mr. Karki never overtly stated that his situation as a landlord is similar to the myth of Chatur Malla, but we indirectly understand this if we know that Karkiji may also lose his land. Indirection, a rhetorical device, is very common in Nepali storytelling in general (S. Miller 1992). Most important, evasiveness and indirection in storytelling absolves the speaker of any responsibility for the information. Thus the common linguistic feature in evasive speech is the verbal post position /-re/, meaning “so they say”. Jãjarkoëi discourse contains hegemonic and counter-hegemonic strains but it also simply produces general meanings (R. Williams 1977:55; Gumperz 1982; Sullivan 1990). Ideology connects the human subject to a more extensive social consciousness by attaching shared meaning to objects, actions, and other symbolic vehicles. All people in Jãjarkoë can interpret something from the myth of Chatur Malla regardless of their social positions as high/low caste, high/low class, villager/urbanite, and insider/outsider. All types of people can relate to the story because it contains central ideologies. It endorses respect for Hindu tradition, 339 reprisal for land theft, adjudication by Kings, suspicion of local political strongmen, and respect for small landowners. Regarding stereotypical semantic features, both Chatur Malla and the little Naiki fall into the semantic domain of /landlord/ which connotes purity, benefaction, ritual cleanliness, and cleverness (chalaki). Perhaps the emotional disturbance of the legend comes from its inversion of Chatur Malla's circumstances from one of being a landlady (recall, she has servants) to one of being a tenant (by implication of having lost her land). Such an inversion of semantic features, from pure to impure, would certainly be disturbing to most listeners. The loss of land for any reason is also a most disturbing subject of myth, legend, or late night gossip for in Jãjarkoë this implies loss of ability to produce one's subsistence. A Lifetime of Labor: Gogane Rawot v Gogane Rawot, the real name of a man who was about 100 years old when I knew him in 1989-90, represented for me much of the transition of a worker from serving one bistã (overlord, patron, employer) to another. In his youth he served the Jãjarkoë King. He brought water up the hill, from the Bheri River up 600 meters to the koë, fortress. He ferried people across the river. And he gave up half his earnings of grain and cash to the King's tax collector. Circa 1953 A. D., after Nepal had become a Panchãyat System and the King's power was essentially removed, Gogane no longer paid tribute to the King. Instead he served local elites as a ferryman and laborer. Gogane had a difficult situation when I interviewed him. Since he was so old, he could not cook for himself. Gogane said that his family, a collection of about thirty people in an extended family of four households, would arrange for his meals while he lived in a small house alone. He complained a lot because the food and quality of care was lacking. Gogane complained that he had no money, his family did not bring food to him regularly, and I, or another patron, should provide him with money. Since the Nepalese government has no senior 340 citizen pension plan, I thought Gogane's requests, far from "whiny" or manipulative, were justified, healthy complaints especially after his years' of service. The following is a synopsis of one visit with him. Our taped interview is translated in the left column. In the right column I present interpretations, information from our other untaped conversations, and background details gleaned from other interviews with him. Utterance Number Gogane's and Jana's Dialogue 1 2 3 4 G: I made and brought 2 tins of ghiu (clarified butter) from Jãjarkoë to Nepalganj. After that I got married. J: How old were you when you married? G: How many years old I was, I don't know. My mom might know, but I don't. My mom and dad have died. Here's my elder son's son (Shows Man Bahadur). They are my grandsons. One daughter I have also. From 1 wife I had 1 son and from the other I had 5 sons. I was a landlord [jamindãri gareko] and kept cows and water buffalo. And after this I did service [chãkaïi] for the king. J: What type of work did you do for the king? 5 G: I would go to the King's home and take them out for hunting. We rode on elephant and hunted elk [jarã]. 6 J: Where did you hunt? Explication Gogane was born in about A.D. 1890. Even in about 1905, when he was preparing to marry, people in Jãjarkoë migrated to the terai to sell ghiu. Like many workers, Gogane does not measure events, like his marriage, in years from birth. Many illiterate workers used relational means to measure dates and remember events. When Gogane said his Mom and Dad have died, the people gathered about all laughed! Of course his own Mom and Dad had died since they would have been 120 years old. Still Gogane situated himself in terms of his relationships to his relatives, pointing out a couple great great nieces and nephews who were standing around listening. One of Gogane's earliest memories of being a worker is his service to Jãjarkoë's Royalty. Gogane is of the Rawot caste, traditionally known for their service as ferrymen. 341 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 G: Daulatpur, (In Barïiya) , Dhangaïi Adda [office name], Belauri Adda, (In Rãjãpur?). We went hunting in Pashaghar and climbed elephants and hunted antelope [the Himalayan Thar: jhãral]. We killed the antelope with guns and made dried meat [sukuti]. J: If you killed animals did the Rãjã give you money or anything? G: Not anything - just lodging and food- that's all. J: How many elephant were there? G: There was 1 elephant driver [mãhute] and 4-5 masters [mãlik] who were the Rãjã or brothers. J: In which months would you go? G: January-February. J: How many animals would be killed at 1 time? G: Only antelope and then gazelle [chittal], wild pig [badel] and birds [?lagnå] but I didn't know before how to kill them. We didn't kill any tigers. 16 J: How many people were there on the hunt? 17 G: The king's family [sãipati]; there were 3 people, the malik, me, and the mahute on the hunt. 18 J: What work did you do? Like other records of work for Nepalese kings, the servants are usually given subsistence but not given a surplus wage of grain or cash. I infer from watching other elephant drivers that Gogane probably assisted in elephant driving but that the expertise was left to the elephant drivers (mãhute/ mahout). 342 19 G: What work did we do? Some carried sand, some stones, some did one thing , some another! Then the bridge wasn't that great and the boats are really better [pul kachhã bo nã pakkã bo]. I was made work leader [mukhyãli] by my father who gave me permission [sanad]. After coming (to the work site) if I got a license they would make me a guard there. But I didn't get a guard's license. The Boating Caste of which Gogane is a member was greatly affected by the new technology of a suspension bridge. Rawots carried people and objects across the Bheri River. They used dried gourds tied around their waists as floats and hauled people on their backs. These floats still can be found drying in sunny spots along the river after people use them. Rawots also carve wooden boats and transport goods as well as people. Most people pay a pound of flour, especially if they are commoners. Elites used to pay nothing and only enticed the Rawots to carry them out of fear or respect. Nowadays everyone gives either some flour or a couple Rupees. 20 G: Mrs. Rana requested in Kathmandu to make the water tank [kaldhãïã] and we made one where there was plenty of water, in Budhbudi. 21 J: What work did you do in the King's house? Gogane describes how he and other workers built the first suspension bridge in Jãjarkoë and the first water tank. This conversation, described in detail in Chapter Three, highlights that many Jãjarkoë is equate their first 'development' projects with these two events. 22 G: In the Raja’s house we received ëikã and the Rãjã gave us a goat, we brought the king 400 [bis bisa] fish in baskets and we gave the king's guard [dyãre] the fish and the guard gave the fish to the king. "Mrs. Rana" refers to a Jãjarkoëi princess named Bal Kumari (Shah) Rana who married the Prime Minister in Kathmandu. 343 23 J: Did he give you money? 24 G: Ha! They didn't give money. They said your service is to kill fish. 25 J: Was there a contractor/overseer? 26 G: No 27 J: Did you ever talk personally with the King? 28 G: No. There was an intermediate. 29 J: Did the intermediate ever beat you? 30 G: No. 31 J: When there was a problem what would happen? Was there court [to settle disputes]? 32 G: There were never any fights. If there were I don't know [what would happen]. If they put anyone in jail, I don't know [about it]. 33 J: Was there the Courthouse (Adãlat)? 34 G:Yes 35 J: Did the Mal Adãlat ever take money for taxes. 36 G: Before, no but from 1989 (1932 A.D.) they did. 37 Listener: Their service was boating and therefore they didn't give them any money. For many generations this has been our work. Half was paid to the ferrymen and half went to the king. The ferrymen would give flour or money at the palace to the tax collector [tekadãr]. The tax collector would come down to the river and also collect money. She was a powerful political figure and she persuaded her husband to authorize several of the first development works in the district. Today the Royal family does not command anyone to hand over in-kind taxes or tribute. But in the early twentieth century most taxes were in kind. The villagers might visit the King's representative, dance and sing all night long, and finally present their tribute. Actually, the Adãlat refers to either the tax office (Mal Adãlat) or the legal courthouse (Adãlat Goswãra). A deep sense of correct behavior in Jãjarkoë is the practice of ådhe, sãjhe, or half to the owner and half to the worker. In this case, the listener (great great nephew?), tries to clarify the relationship between boaters, or any workers for that matter, and owners. 344 38 J: Did you have any land? 39 G: I had some once upon a time but the river took my land. I've got no land, no irrigated land, no dryland these days. These days I go without anything. Nothing...nothing. 40 J: How was the land before? 41 G: Before it was good land, it was irrigated land. Now I'm only chiseling away the days [din kãtne]. 42 J: After the land was lost, what did you do? Did the Rãjã give you any land? The listener uses the ideal of adhe, half, to describe the historically correct economic relationship between those perceived to own the resources and those perceived to work on the resources. In another interview Gogane described how the King offered the households in the valley by the river either strips of their own land next to the river or land higher up. This was probably like a birta land grant. The Rawot said they wanted the land near the river so that they could more easily haul up water to irrigate, and so they could have land next to where they fish. They were greedy to want the best land, Gogane said. For that they were punished. The river began to flood, and it carried away the beautiful soil. It began to leave salts on the soil and the soil died, turning slowly from sandy loam to sandy sand. 43 G: No. I plowed for others and worked for others. If they gave me work then I ate. 44 J: How did you do ãdhiyå? There wasn't a messenger in Rawotgau then, only a village headman [mukhiyã]. 45 G: Same as now. Half for us and half [sãjhe] for the other. Made equal [sãjhe garne]. These days people also do ëeka but then we didn't have ëeka. Teka means to rent land. It is not a common practice in Jãjarkoë. 345 46 J: And your father's work? 47 G: Cutting and carrying wood. If the king orders him to contact somebody then he goes and does that...just like messenger [katuwãl] work but he wasn't a full messenger. 48 J: What did the village headman do then? 49 G: Nothing. Just sit and eat. If a guest came to the village, the mukhiyã The Mukhiyã, village headman, was one of puts them up. He would hear the King's go-betweens to whom Gogane disputes. would have given some tribute, such as the household surtax. 50 J: What did your mom do? (Standard Nep: pãle); "Pãlye" was 51 G: After bearing children she took care another riotous word choice and everyone of us [hãmilai pãlye]. She went to laughed. People raise animals as in others' homes to work on the diki and "bokrãle pãlnu" [to raise goats] but one to grind grain [jãnto pisne]. does not usually raise children like 52 G: Then there was no water mill animals! [ghaëëa] and therefore they had to grind and eat (grain) If they gave Technologies changed from mainly hand some grain after the work that was her grinding of grains using the diki and jãnto pay. toward using water and one electrical 53 J: What was the dãrbãr (village powered mills. I think Gogane is incorrect square) like? stating that there were no water mills in 54 G:The dãrbãr was built, the tax office his childhood since old stone wheels look was built too. to me like they have been used in past centuries. The environmental changes in general, too, have changed since Gogane's boyhood. The region around the District Capital is now intensively farmed yet it used to be jungle or forest nearly to the top of the Capital. 55 J: Where'd you marry your wife? 56 G:We married in Rawotgau. It was our own decision. 57 J: Were marriage customs different then? Gogane's opinion was that the City square [Dãrbãr] was a place where nobility lived, where administrators opened offices, and where many people needed the fish, water, and grains from the land below where Gogane lived. Gogane's love marriage was typical in that he did not presume to arrange a marriage. He actually had several wives over the course of his life. 346 58 G:Then we had no money, no big marriage ceremony. It's not like having money these days, before there wasn't any money. [ãjabãlã jastã paisã nãì UIL paisã nãì] From Gogane's perspective, marriages involving a lot of planning and money are different from styles he witnessed as a youth. [This translates to standard Nepali: aja boli ko jasto paisã hoina pãhile paisã thiena.] While there are many metanarrative and prosodic features which we could discuss, I wish to direct attention to the narrative itself. Surprisingly, Gogane does much more than his ritual caste service of boating and providing fish to the King. Gogane depicts a common strategy of workers which involves both unskilled and skilled labor. Over his lifetime, Gogane carried out many types of work: subsistence farming and livestock raising, service for the king (chakaïi), elephant caretaking, sharecropping (adhiyå), boating, fishing, trading ghee, unpaid government labor (begãr, jhara, sramadãn), and casual labor (jãla, baure). In other interviews, rarely did workers mention doing so many different types of work, yet most conducted two or three major types of labor in a single year. Even artisan households often split their labor, for example, women pursue livestock herding, firewood selling, and petty trade while the men conduct artisanship. Because low castes and other marginal households do many types of unskilled and skilled labor demonstrates, to apply the term jajmãni to this ferryman's economic ties with patrons essentializes the scope of the artisan's work and labor relations. Applying only the epithet jajmãni creates an overgeneralization because many labor obligations are ignored in favor of focus on jajmãni. Using jajmãni to signify many types of labor has also overshadowed the work that women do and their roles in labor exchange networks. If Gogane's mother was typical of women today, for example, she worked up to fifty percent more in a given day than Gogane’s father (Acharya and Bennett 1981). If we choose to apply the term jajmãni as an umbrella for the many different sorts of labor relations, we generally cannot also focus on particular labor relations and the work of subordinate groups. 347 Gogane's life stories are important because he lives at a nexus where rural country joins District Center and this is the epicenter of exploitation in Jãjarkoë. The hill-to-valley relationship of /high: low/ mirrors the labor status hierarchy of /owner : worker/ and the power relationship of /strong : weak/. When Gogane was young, his village, "Rawotgau," was just a tiny satellite of the administrative center, Jãjarkoë. His village is located at the geographical point where the King could exploit the ferrymen's village for all of the hilltop's everyday needs, including procurement of fish, water, servants, and firewood. More distant villages provided tribute as well: grain, cloth, vegetable oil, and even wild vegetables. But jungle-hidden villages were not under direct control of the Jãjarkoë King as was the village of the ferrymen. To extract taxes from distant villages the King would have to send tax collectors walking for a day or more into the rural forests. Thus Gogane's village has been highly exploited compared to distant jungle hidden villages. Today the King resides in Kathmandu yet Rawotgau's workers have become more necessary than ever to the hilltop landlords and administrative elites. These elites own most of the rich top-grade irrigated ricelands in the valleys surrounding Rawotgau. From Rawotgau come the sharecroppers and daily laborers who provide the grain, vegetables, and other subsistence needs of administrative officers, their families, and other landed elites. As one considers Goganeji's reminiscences, one may notice no references to high caste, Brãhmanical social proscriptions. Brãhmanical principles generally include the knowledge, practice, and enforcement of hierarchy, caste ideals, dharma, karma, dowry, patrilocality, chastity, arranged marriage, and taboos against remarriage of women. These are all aspects of important guiding principles of correct social behavior according to Hindu tradition. However, many low castes, workers, and commoners do not follow Brãhmanical proscriptions and do not refer to them in their informal discussion of proper behavior. Are these high Hindu principles perhaps merely gatekeeping concepts set up by elites of how society ought to be seen as operating? From the subaltern perspective of low caste workers like Goganeji, such elite 348 concepts have little substantive meaning. Rather, concepts of equality, fairness, proper patronage, honesty, and harmony represent pertinent ethics by which to live and work. By understanding and accepting the validity of these value orientations, several arguably new cultural ethics emerge as significant metonyms of South Asian society which are held by nonelites. One of these semantic vehicles for the expression of proper labor relations which is found within sharecropping is the concept of adhé (See utterances #37 and 45). Meaning literally "half," adhé (> adhiyå) implies that something, usually grain, is made over into equal shares between owner and worker. The concept of adhé connotes equality, a sense of social fairness, of even a contract fulfilled. vi Obviously, disenfranchised householders need such a concept to lay claim to their basic human rights of subsistence. For householders who cannot read or manipulate written documents, the power of social contract through invoking adhé over a share of the produce becomes a powerful metonym of social relations between workers and owners. A related concept, often used by workers like Goganeji who practice casual labor and daily labor, is that of sãjhe meaning "cooperation." Sãjhe implies that labor giver and labor receiver have achieved some sort of parity, some agreement which enables them to work together harmoniously. Again, the illiterate laborer has no legal rights of cooperation and fairness from his or her employer. To minimize exploitation the daily laborer needs the reassurance and relative safety of an institutionalized cooperative relationship. If both sides can agree on a proper course of action, then both labor giver and receiver benefit, a condition which workers seek but often do not attain. Thus sãjhe becomes the signifier of cooperative work relations in asymmetrical work environments. A relationship inherent in many asymmetrical work arrangements, patronage is found universally, even in completely capital intensive societies (see utterances #3-9; 22-24; 46-47). In Nepal people rarely think of their social status without thinking of who they are in 349 relationship to their political and economic patrons. Many terms allude to this state in which an unequal exchange of symbolic, political, economic, and/or cultural resources ensue. Bista, mitbuwa, chakaïi (utterance #3), khalo dinne manchhe, and sauji are all terms fraught with the hierarchies of patron to client bonds. Thus a jajmãni relationship, like Gogane's work as ferryman for elite patrons, contains patronage but it also almost invariably involves other labor relationships which are codified in practices such as sharecropping, daily labor, and bonded labor. Patronage in the Life of a Goldsmith Named Bhãrat Sunãr One of the key features of patronage is the asymmetrical yet cooperative social tie between patron and service specialist. In Jãjarkoë the artisan or the sharecropper usually has a close bond with his/her patron. Low castes in general keep a paternal bond with high castes either through short term work such as household chores or long term bonds such as indebtedness. Fealty may be emotionally a positive relationship in that each partner relies on the other. Just as easily it can be marked by antagonism, as when a low caste constantly has to defend his or her actions to the patron, as for example, in the account of a sharecropper in Chapter Seven. The account of Bhãrat Sunãr, below, explores his family's conflicts with high caste neighbors and the support that another high caste family extends to the Sunãr. Bhãrat is the head of an extended family of Sunãr who live in the District Capital and nearby. No one in the family has a school education but some have done technical training in weaving and water management. Their socio-economic status is poor by high caste standards, yet they are quite enterprising; the Sunãr do weaving, goldsmithing, fruit planting, subsistence farming, and wage labor. Bhãrat's son has patrons within about a two day's walking distance. Bhãrat is fortunate to have his name appear as mohi (tenant) on the land deed of the landowning A. Shah family. Mohi status gives the Sunãr family rights to occupation, a percentage of profit if the landlord sells the land, and protection from arbitrary eviction. Bhãrat's family is 350 resourceful, they have a little bit of their own land, half a hectare in Bhãrat's name, half a hectare in one of his wive's name, and they rent land. The family members that I dealt with on a daily basis were Bhãrat's nephew, Ladãkh, and his niece, Bhimalã because they worked for the farm at which I usually stayed. Bhimalã and Ladãkh both work at Grihasti, an NGO in the area. They do planting, take care of the seed nursery, and cook. Bhimalã can be found more often doing domestic cleaning, washing, sweeping and Ladãkh more often does maintenance work and travels to satellite Grihasti farms. Bhimalã took weaving training and this makes her the most educated of her family. She is resourceful enough to have financed her own loom, no mean feat given the attitude of the Agricultural Development Bank's lending officers toward low caste women. Bhãrat's family currently is in dispute with their Shaha landowners. According to Bhãrat, the landowners agreed to sell some of their rented land. Bhãrat paid about U. S. $1,300 for the land (circa 1989 A.D.). Legally the title transfers only after a waiting period. During that period the landowners changed their mind and didn't give a land deed or money back to Bhãrat. They did remove Bhãrat's name from the mohi registration section however. To get vii Bhãrat's name off the registration appears to have been their real motive in selling the land. Having lost both his life's savings and his rented land, Bhãrat is fighting the land swindle in court. As we were talking one evening, Bhãrat told a story of land asseveration that happened when he was a youth. It happened in the 1920's when the influence of Jãjarkoëi kings was still powerful. Bhãrat's family aligns in this story to the Shaha kings. The evil landgrabbers take the form of a "Shahi" family, another high caste though not of noble origins. Several surrounding circumstances informed the content of Bhãrat's speech which follows. First, we had been invited to visit Bhãrat and interview him about goldsmithing and his farming. This meant that an old low caste man was inviting into his home a set of odd but powerful guests: the high caste son of the most prominent lawyer in the District Center, a 351 foreign woman with no near relatives, and an permaculturalist/British ex - patriot. Bhãrat was pleased yet nervous about serving dinner to such a group. This collection of guests certainly influenced his choice of storytelling. Perhaps he chose to talk of royal patrons given his current collection of guests. Perhaps also he spoke of major deities rather than local ones given our familiarity with greater Hindu traditions. Utterance Number Translation 1 Bhãrat: Lakshya and Parbe Sunãr were two brothers, there were no others. They took care of my daughter and from now on I'm old enough so I thought that now I should also take care of them. Before this, [the Queen gave the order that] Lakshya and Parbe should be the first caretakers of the new water tank and so she sent [Lakshya and Parbe] to Kathmandu. They took the [water tank technical] training and they got the opportunity to begin the water tank flowing. 2 In order to do that our Kharke and Lakshya Sunãr went to Kathmandu and got the training. After they got the training and had passed, they came and started the water flowing [from the water tank]. First our Dad [Parbe] and Kharke Sunãr, our "big" brother, [actually] our father's younger brother, came to Tilomari Khanki and after that Lakshya also had to be at Tilomari Khanki. When they went to Tilomari Khanki they encountered the Captain [Hari Bikram Shaha] [living] at Pipaldãda. 3 Bhãrat: There are families [living] on the upper side [of the hill] and they can play with the water but we have to drink it; they can't do this, and we had to stop these things. Comments Bhãrat took care of Lakshya and Parbe in the past but they have since died. When they [those living uphill] had to stop they filed a complaint with the King. Bhãrat means that after the water tank got started some people, especially the Shahi family who he later mentions, abused the water privileges. They washed their clothes or animals in the same water that people downhill also used. The "queen" refers to Mrs. Bal Kumari Rana. She was a member of Jãjarkoëi royalty who married the Rana Prime Minister in Kathmandu in the 1920's. The water tank was the first development work constructed in Jãjarkoë District. It was built in the 1920's. Other workers had many jobs on the early development projects. Some carried earth, some took care of elephants, some ferried people across the river, some were overseers, some were accountants, etc. The Sunãr got the job of turning the water tank on and off. Tilomari Khanki is a place name. It is near Budbudhi, where the water tank is nearby located HBS is an ally in the story. He is a relative of the King Upendra. (brother ?) Pipaldãda is a village near the water tank. 352 4 5 6 7 The Judge warned them (the Shahis) "You're going to lose." After 2-4 years' of this Prithivi Narayan Shaha, in a sudden change, gave them a bottle [figurative; like a "pot"] full of money. They got clever [chalak], with 3 people on [government] salary they got more and more clever every month. Gyane: Yeah. Bhãrat: Pretty soon they were very rich. Like this they started to raise horses and buffalo, the women too were getting too much, because they, Taramara and the others, were wearing gold jewelry and they were raising horses, buffalo, cattle. Nowadays that place where Ram Shahi lives used to be ours. Gyane: Yeah. Bhãrat refers to high castes who live uphill, perhaps the Shahi extended family. "Prithivi Narayan Shaha" may refer to a judge in the region at the time, or a close relative of the King at the time, Upendra Bikram Shaha. To get a government job is a very coveted sort of employment. If a family has three members earning money in the 1920's, this would be very advantageous, "clever" for the family. Gyane is my research assistant, a resident of Jãjarkoë. Without banks, wealth is stored in movable property (chal sampatti). Women controlled much of the movable property, especially the livestock and their jewelry. Men could of course sell the jewelry, but women mainly had the usufruct rights of movable property. Bhãrat introduces by name his main antagonist, "Ram Shahi." Bhãrat: Yeah, here, and we wanted to Ram Shahi took Bhãrat's land. As often raise our cattle and buffalo here and on the happens, the litigant asseverated the other side too but we just left it. We property and brought a case to make the couldn't have even filed a case [against action legal. them]. Well they went and filed a case a little later for the favorable land, case #1465 is the number which they gave us. In order to get our wealth they filed case #1465. 9 Gyane: Why why? 10 Bhãrat: They just said we stole it [the land]. Shortly afterwards all the Sunãr began to get haijã [cholera]. The kalariyã or haijã. The kalariyã or haijã they got all year' long. Ram Shahi claimed the Sunãr were illegally They were even dying beside us, in the next squatting on the disputed land. house. Cholera is endemic in the area even today. 8 353 11 The cholera broke out and every day it was like people would rise up and die down from haijã; haijã was just like that. Kalariyã, it used to be called haijã. That's haijã too where you can just die. 12 So it was like that in the nearest house For high castes to claim that illiterate low and after they died they [Ram Shahi's castes have taken their land is a common family] simply took over the empty house. source of land disputes. While we cannot That's how they turned our case upside know "Ram Shahi's" side of the story, Bhãrat claims high caste deception. down and said it was their own house but others said it was not and eventually a case got filed [against the Sunãr]. Well who among us should be first [the main person] to defend us in the case? 13 Respected Saihila [literally, "third-oldest While the Sunãrs did effectively lose the case, brother"] started us off. Respected saihila Bhãrat still defers to the support of Mrs. brother led the way and we backed him up Rana in Kathmandu. in the case. And the case went on and oooonnnn....to Kathmandu we fought. When we arrived in Kathmandu we were asked, "Who are you?" The news [of the muddã or court case] spread to Her Royal Majesty the Queen. She said, "Oh No! This shall not be a case! The men [the Sunãr] aren't going to become tenants." When the case was cancelled, this means usually that the Judge dismisses the litigant's And after that the case was... claims as faulty. In this way the Sunãr won... 14 Gyane: Cancelled [kyansil bhayo]. 15 Bhãrat: [Laughing] Cancelled. Later, but, they only reclaimed a small portion of their after all was said and done, Hari Bikram extended family's holdings. Shaha [HBS] came here. HBS came and our Father greeted him. HBS rode elephant Contra to the Shahis, HBS was a close relative when he visited the Queen's palace. His (brother? son?) of the King. Bhãrat again aligns himself with the royalty and against own father was a General but unlike the the Shahi high caste of no noble origins. General, HBS rode elephant when he came "Shahi" is a lower caste than "Shaha." to call. When they [neighbors and relatives] found out HBS was coming to Parbe Sunãr's place they were surprised. 16 On the lower side there's a red house, Bhãrat actively pointed to the location of the straight down the way. Well our house is houses, even though it was dark out and we over on one side, and there is our were sitting inside. opponent's house kind of in the middle. I think "2%" [se ko dwi persent] is more a loose Our situation being like that HBS Colonel term for "a small part" rather than a said "Hey! Listen! carefully divided portion of land in this case. 354 They [Ram Shahi] have to give 2% of the land to you." That's how the Sunãr got the land. 17 After they got the lands the khet was full of trees. The reason is because the land was never plowed. The land they received was not tilled. Being 'full of trees' is bad because they have to completely cut and condition the new farmland. In this story political factions existed; local landlords created a problem for the Sunãr while absentee landlords did not. The Sunãr opposed the Chhetri high castes, in the form here of "Ram Shahi" who formed the local landowning elite. And at the same time the Sunãr alignd with their Thakuri caste patrons in the form of the Shahas, the Queen and King and family, including Hari Bikram Shaha. Local landlords created a problem for the Sunãr; absentee landlords did not. Absentee landowning elites of directly royal lineage moved their wealth to Kathmandu and posed no material threat to the Sunãr. Today, the urban elite nobility's new goal and interest is to promote the welfare of low castes which creates another thread of alliance between low caste (faithful servant) and nobility. A telling event in Bhãrat's story is the cholera epidemic and its devastating effect on the land ownership rights of the Sunãr extended family (#10-12). Bhãrat's tale gives graphic evidence that "natural disasters" such as epidemics often create just the right conditions for land asseveration and seizure of other resources such as fishing and cattle pastures by dominant elites. Further, when disenfranchised groups like the Sunãr do sue to reclaim lands, they wind up with 'two percent' of their original which is not even cultivated farmland (#16). viii Becoming part of the royal feudal bureaucracy was truly one of the few ways to gain any measure of stability for land poor families. Bhãrat described his family's access to water technical training as their most important distinguishing economic strategy. He described how their nemesis, the extended family of Taramara and Ram Shahi, gained three salaried spots in the tiny Jãjarkoëi bureaucracy of the 1920's (#4-6). Bhãrat Sunãr's moral alliance with nobility even recreates itself in his religious and political rendering of fealty to the King of Nepal. Bhãrat confessed a nationalistic concern over 355 Nepal's relationship to India, specifically in border disputes between Nepal and India. Nepal has often felt itself to be the weak neighbor of both China and India. Politicians often quote King Birendra Bikram Shaha, "We [Nepal] are a yam between two stones." Bhãrat demonstrates his allegiance to the noble layer of society as he identifies with the King's problems of land ownership: Utterance Number Translation 1 Bhãrat: At that time Prithivi Narayan wanted to destroy the valley. They made a pact with the other nation [India]. India deceived Nepal and said it would give a big piece of land [to Nepal]. The King and a priest were thinking one way and India tricked them. 2 So India said fine and told Nepal it will get the thick skin of land but in reality when Nepal got its lands in the treaty it only got the thin skins. The land that it already had before, Lucknow, used to be part of Nepal but we lost that in the treaty. Maybe the King thought we'd get the chicken thigh of the land but India deceived us; they gave us the thiiiinnneeessst piece of skin! 3 Our so kind King (sojo raja) was deceived by India! They made us really weak. We were really mad. Maybe someday we're gonna beat India. Nepal has lots of power. Why are we powerful? Here we've got Vishnu, and Sita - Janaki - was born here in Nepal. Well Ram was born in India, so they have a male born there and that's pretty powerful. Over there Power (shakti), the male, was born and here Lakshmi, Wealth, was born. Comments Prithivi Narayan Shaha [PNS] was the first King of present-day Nepal and he "unified" Nepal circa 1768 A.D. PNS came from Gorkha, outside the Kathmandu Valley and therefore had to burn the valley several times to subdue the local Kings. India helped PNS with armaments but didn't give up land. Later, India clashed with Nepal in regional disputes over lands around Darjeeling and Lucknow. Both the regions west and east of Nepal were ceded to India. Many people in these regions still speak Nepali. Everyone I met from Sikkim could speak Nepali, for example. The King of Nepal is an incarnation of Vishnu. Janaki is a major site in Nepal, known as Janakpur in the lowlands. Lakshmi is the Goddess of material and metaphysical wealth. Lakshmi alludes to Nepal's spiritual wealth, good weather, mountain waters, etc. In the circumstances of power, males have a Shiva is the destroyer god, powerful and little bit more power than the women. present at the end and rebirth of creation. Although we have a little power, Shiva's place too is in Nepal. 356 Krishna: Maheshwor was from here too, from Kailash, before those places were part of Nepal. Bhãrat: Palpung! 5 Krishna: From below to Lucknow, all of it! 6 Gyane: From Sikkim to Almoda! 7 Bhãrat: Our King's power was great! He was Bhãgwan and the Queen is the Pipal tree and all the people are shaded by her. The King's roots are everywhere. He gets along well with other nations (milaune). India really nips [khãi khãi khãi khãi] away at us. What to do [Ke garne?] Our King's so powerful, knowledgeable, Ke garne? 4 Krishna works for Suhasthi; he is an expatriot from Britain. Everyone is getting excited about Nepal's great history. Bhagwan is one deity's epithet. The Pipal tree is sacred. Gautama Buddha was born under the Pipal. Land is equated with food, with meat, with sustenance (#2). It is the form of nourishment which sustains life and in this metaphorical use we understand the meaning of land as a means of surviving. Unlike other forms of food, meat is a privilege and a prestigious food form. In religious events all family and friends are invited to partake of the prestige food, meat, but the poor receive only minimal or token amounts as in a bit of the skin while the most powerful and central characters receive such succulent parts as the chicken thigh. Thus Bhãrat plays on Nepal's image as the poor neighbor to overstuffed India. The straight and kind person is often deceived by the "clever" [chalakh] person and Bhãrat renders the King as sojo [straight/honest] and a milãune [person who fits; harmonious] person in his dealings with both other countries and with His subjects (#3, #7). These descriptive words are quite important signifiers of Bhãrat's value orientations. Bhãrat often stressed in everyday discourse ethics of egalitarianism, cooperation, and fairness in addition to honesty and harmony. He rarely stressed ideals of hierarchy or enforced ideals of purity and pollution in the manner of elite Hindus. Two terms which especially reflect cultural attitudes of proper labor relations are sojo and milaune. Sojo implies that the subject referred to is upright, honest, or most literally "straight;" and milaune literally means "to get along well with (others)" or in English we would 357 call such a person "harmonious." From a working class perspective (if we indeed can use the notion of social classes) these terms imply that the patron or work partner will make a fair deal and not be exploitative. In dealing with others of a symmetrical social standing, the concepts of honesty and harmony frequently refer to social contracts where hard work and commitment are involved, such as during harvesting. In dealing with elites and asymmetrical relationships, honesty and harmony are cited as important qualities for the "good patron." During ironic commentary, householders often state that the subject being commented upon is "Very honest" (kasto sojo) while holding up a bent forefinger in non-verbal protest of the subject's dishonest behavior. The working class's ideals of equality, fairness, sharing, cooperation, good patronage, honesty, and harmony are voiced by workers often in contexts which comment upon work relations. When viewed from the "bottom up" we see a visible shift from a focus on hierarchy to a focus on equality. The high caste ideals of purity, pollution, hierarchy, dharma, karma, arranged marriage, and proper marriage proscriptions in general all dissolve into relatively unimportant organizing principles for common householders such as low castes and workers. There's a real truth to Bhãrat's metaphor that the Male [India] is powerful and the Female [Nepal] is rich (#3). Nepal has historically been known to India as the Kingdom which has great forests (Ayurvedic medicine, wood, wool from cool climate sheep), incredible water supplies, a pleasant and healthy climate. Indians romanticized Nepal's mountains and nature as a place where infinite wisdom, ultimate truth, and the peace of detachment from earthly desires could be achieved. Nepal is where Indian ascetics often sought to find attainment. Bhãrat believes that Lakshmi, Shiva, and Vishnu, his 'deity-patrons' (or 'patron-deities') personify Nepal's conflict with India (#3-7). It is a war of power using a religious analogy. An educated person would discuss the resources and power of Nepal and India and compare statistics, historical dates, details of treaties. Bhãrat used religious analogy and we immediately understand the relationship of Nepal and India's land and power. 358 Krishna, Gyane, and Bhãrat almost literally were singing songs of praise as they recited the glory of Nepal's borders when they stretched from Sikkim to Almoda, Lucknow to western Tibet (at Kailash. Bhãrat doesn't forget to include his King and Queen in the deified circle, either as his Queen "shades" her subjects in the form of the sacred Pipal tree and the King takes the form of nature's foundation and preserver since the King is the living avatãr of Vishnu (#7). Finally Bhãrat bemoans Nepal's land-poor state in the phrase, "Ke garne? Ke garne?" (Literally: "What to do?") One of the meanings of this phrase insinuates an almost hopeless state of affairs (#7). In this context it could signify Bhãrat's despair at being "khãi khãi khãi khãi" (khãnu, "to eat") or nipped away at like a dog nips at a beggar. So while Bhãrat recognizes his (patron) King's power, he also recognizes the fated state of relations, of property, politics, and power, in which Nepal is embroiled with India. Bhãrat used many markers of social relations in addition to word choices, though I haven't highlighted these in the translation. Most notable were the metaphors, prosodic features, social registers, and relational patronyms. "Meat," "Thick skin," and "Chicken thigh" signify wealth, health, power, and success. "Thin skin" and "Weakness" signify poverty, powerlessness, lack of cleverness, inability to bargain for wealth. Bhãrat uses deified metaphors of power, citing Vishnu, Janaki, Bhagwãn, and Lakshmi as metaphors of the state of Nepal. Bhãrat's prosody emphasized his feelings of state powerlessness in relations with India. The "Thiiiinnneeessst (masino) piece of skin" signified India's immense deception while "India really nips (khãi khãi khãi khãi) signifies the constant bickering in state relations between India and Nepal. The metaphorical use of "eating" is a common theme in Jãjarkoë. The verb is used for many actions besides the actual physical act of ingesting food such as bribery and land grabbing (paisa khanu: to eat money). In verb selections, Bhãrat frequently used the royal pronominal and verb forms (hazur baksinu) rather than simply honorifics (tapai hunu). Bhãrat's talk about productive relations involving landowners, sharecroppers, elites, and commoners is not at all unique. All men and women assess and discuss changes in the work 359 relationships of their neighbors. It becomes difficult to actually assert that it is land holding sizes or other material conditions which influence social relations rather than talk about land deals and wealth which influences members of Jãjarkoëi society. In these case though, gossip, rhetoric, political grandstanding and other types of manipulative speech acts contribute much more to actual productive social relations than anthropologists who study material conditions generally ascribe. Concluding Assertions The first assertion which has guided this chapter is that symbols convey social status as much as material circumstances. Not only are work relationships evident in overt material ways, such as in land holding sizes, education, and house types, but many fleeting icons and messages convey relative statuses. As Dick Hebdige noted, "...the tensions between dominant and subordinate groups can be found reflected in the surfaces of subcultures - in the styles made up of mundane objects which have a double meaning." (1979: 2). My personal interpretations of labor relationships while living in Jãjarkoë often were deciphered from mundane objects such as broken army issue tennis shoes, swatches of homemade cotton waist wraps, flour sifters made by the leather workers, various buttons and badges and other objects which signified labor and social status. Though I focused in this chapter on speech acts more than decipherment of mundane objects, language utterances are similar "little mundane objects." Like other symbols, texts and utterances also connote social and labor status. ix In this chapter I have used excerpts of conversations to highlight some of the tensions present between people in asymmetrical work relations. A second assertion which has guided this chapter is that personal experiences often highlight general rules about labor relations. Fredric Jameson (1981) imaginatively draws many parallels between narratives and their wider social significance, which is what each of the textual examples in this chapter have done. Just as Bhãrat Sunãr links his own experiences of 360 land asseveration with the experiences common to sharecroppers and tenants, so this is the transformational power of all narratives. Stories transform personal experience into representational structures. In imagining one's lived experiences related to those of others, stories of labor relations transform experience into universal histories. This is why we can read about a widow's loss of land, for example, and understand that this landowner, like landowners universally, reacted with vengeance. This is why we can empathize with impoverished Gogane Rawot's adoption of many types of skilled and unskilled labor in order to survive. We understand that universally, the most destitute households must be abjectly open to every work opportunity. Finally, a third assertion which has guided this chapter is that cultural expressions are intrinsic to the meaning of labor. I could explain all the overt rules for appropriate behavior in the practices of Jãjarkoëi sharecropping, bonded labor, casual labor, etc., yet still something would be missing. This "something" one might describe as the intrinsic meaning, the hermeneutic insight, attached to labor practice. There might be political reasons, historical conditions, or economic strictures which constrain the meaning of labor and labor relations in this given geographical region, yet explication of labor practice ultimately comes from understanding the symbolic significance of labor within the larger society. One might say that we must seek to understand the dialectic between labor action and symbolic reflection of labor action before labor becomes culturally meaningful. Notes to Chapter Eight iOne might interpret being not lazy and being a cooperative person as mediating semantic features within a dualist structural paradigm. There are of course many mediating features (up - middle - down) though my goal here is to simply note the stereotypical features of workers and owners (nonworkers). ii I wrote down both sankar and sãnch as meaning the conch shell. I believe Karkiji said only one of these words but given my language ablilities, I did not perceive and note the difference at the time. 361 iii iv v Note similarities and differences between the Chatur Malla legend and the story by Kovalan, the ancient Indian author, of the man who commits åtmãhatyã due to unrequitted love. Actually, Bharat Sunãr once used the word shakti to describe the King of Nepal. "Gogane" is an interesting name since it means "Oak tree." Gogane claimed to be 108 years' old and having lived so long, certainly is like an oak tree in this respect. vi While I personally believe the practice of adhiyå sharecropping is arguably exploitative, I admit that others in Jãjarkoë may not see it this way. When Goganeji says that adhiyå is a tradition, he doesn't necessarily imply that it is a fair tradition but one which provides subsistence. vii 1 Hectare = approximately 20 Nepalese Ropani. In 1986-87, 1 U.S. dollar = approximately 18 Nepalese Rupees; in 1989-90, 1 U.S. dollar = approximately 29 Nepalese Rupees. In 1993 1 U.S. dollar = approximately 49 Nepalese Rupees. Inflation has been about 15% per year. viii This story has its own "internal validity" which is not necessarily what other people would recount, especially members of the Shahi contingent. My goal is to examine beliefs and cultural expressions of productive relationships rather than to explore the "objective" realities of any given dispute. ix Language has some differences compared to other symbols, of course. For example, a text is always in a state of process whereas objects may be completed. Also, texts are not usually forms of alienated labor whereas objects often do represent alienated labor. There is not a perfect homology between the production of texts and the production of goods (Jameson 1981: 45). 365 9 CONCLUSION: EXCHANGE AND POWER IN NEPALI SOCIETY Work is an activity that everyone participates in. But everyone is not always happy with their work. Since people work for up to about 12 hours per day, the nature of how people feel about their work, how they organize it, and how they relate to each other during work is particularly important. As another author recently wrote, “By the work that a society chooses to do or not do (italics original), it defines its values and shapes its future.” (Boldt 1993). When I began my inquiries into the nature of working relationships in Jãjarkoë, I knew that particular non-capitalist traditions of working existed in Jãjarkoë. I knew about the “system” of jajmãni, in which all service specialists, such as artisans and priests, were supposedly bound to a set of patrons through reciprocal obligations and ritual duties. I soon found out that jajmãni had many geographical variants and perhaps so many that the term jajmãni was meaningless or at least unhelpful. It became apparent that the Sanskritic meaning of jajmãni was used in Jãjarkoë, meaning that jajmãni was a relationship between priest and high caste patron only and it emphatically did not include artisans. For artisan - landowner relations, the relationships and obligations were called khalo. I also came to Jãjarkoë to study the cooperative labor form known as parimã simple labor reciprocity, but I did not connect parimã with jajmãni and khalo. I found out however, that these practices were indeed all part of a range of labor options, and that a householder’s adoption of one practice or another depended upon economic situation, social caste and class, and other circumstances. After reflecting on these working relationships, noticing that they are often exploitative yet also often full of cooperative symmetry between households, I felt that an understanding of local labor 366 management had to go beyond value judgements of good or bad, cooperative or exploitative, symmetrical or asymmetrical. Slowly the realization formed in my mind that I had been seeing the particular but not the general situation. I had come to this study with a Western conception that it was important to study domination and subordination and all the dualisms of caste and class which this entails. I had picked apart the network of exchange relationships according to what I had been taught. If I had, as Foucault (1977) councils, reduced the anthropologically assigned unities of discourse labeled “caste,” “jajmãni,” and “hierarchy,” to a field of information or statements, I could have better understood that these concepts were preventing me from understanding the greater system of indigenous labor relations. Instead, I gradually realized that beyond the hierarchies of caste and jajmãni lies a totality which is constituted by labor practices which are simultaneously egalitarian, hierarchical, and negotiated. The character of working in Nepalese society really is different than in other societies. This diffence may be grasped by studying the “ethnomanagement” of work in Nepal. By “ethnomanagement,” I am referring to the act, manner, or practice of handling, supervision, or control over work for productive ends, the prefix “ethno-” referring to local, indigenous i approaches which occur within a culturally demarcated community or region. The character of working in Nepalese society is filled with meanings which Nepalese people place upon plowing, leisure, migrancy, etc. which are loaded with implications which are not totally translatable into English societal meanings. And these meanings are based in part upon historical circumstances that have occurred in Nepal. For example, a friend from Manushi, an NGO with an office in Kathmandu, stopped by my house one day. She observed that many Nepalese were migrating into Kathmandu from the countryside. They only wanted to make a little money and then head back home come planting season. And by extention, many Nepalese were also heading for the apple orchards, construction projects, and even into prostition in India for part of the year. The Nepalese with little or no land want desperately to earn just a little 367 money and are willing to migrate away from their homes for part of the year. But there is a balance between migration for wage labor and subsistence agriculture which is particularly Nepalese in character (Feldman and Fournier 1976; Dahal et al. 1977; Gurung 1989). Almost all Nepalese people have at least a little land and are not completely landless. Since reportedly more than 93% of production in Nepal takes place in the agrarian sector (HMG 1992), one might assume that the study of agricultural labor management is an important subject of social science and cultural research in Nepal. Further, since Nepali agriculture is small scale, labor intensive, technologically simple, and geared toward subsistence, one might assume that the study of indigenous labor management systems would be an important aspect of social science research and development. To some extent there has been an effort to promote research of indigenous labor relations and of small scale knowledge systems in Nepal (Andors 1974; Bhatt et al. 1992; Blustain 1984; Bouillier 1977; Brower 1990; L. Caplan 1972; P. Caplan 1972; Feldman and Fournier 1976; Gurung 1987a; 1987b; Hoffpauir 1978; Humphery 1992; Ishii 1982; Krause 1988; Levine 1980; Manzardo 1985; Martin 1986; Messerschmidt 1981; 1982; Metz 1989; Miller 1956; Muller-Boker 1991; Okada 1957; Prindle 1976; 1977; M. C. Regmi 1978; 1982; Stone 1989; Toffin 1986a; 1986b; Yoder 1986; Zurick 1990.) The subject of indigenous knowledge in Nepali agriculture is beginning to expand into topics such as forestry management, soil conservation, labor relations, and applications of indigenous knowledge. Perhaps the inability to see past the "gatekeeping" concept of jajmãni stems from the need to reduce South Asian economic life to something manageable to the outsider (Appadurai 1986). Since Charlotte and William Wiser wrote about the jajmãni system in 1930, cultural researchers have been fascinated by the concept , practice, and ethical implications of this form of patron-clientage. The concept of jajmãni, a sort of village republic in which all households exchange particular rights and obligations over grain and services according to the household's 368 caste position, has literally "won out" over other types of labor relationships as a dominant metonym in cultural studies of indigenous labor management. As A. Appadurai observes, "...a few simple theoretical handles become metonyms and surrogates for the civilization or society as a whole: hierarchy in India, honor - and shame in the circum-Mediterranean, filial piety in China are all examples of what one might call gatekeeping concepts in anthropological theory, concepts, that is, that seem to limit anthropological theorizing about the place in question, and that define the quintessential and dominant questions of interest in the region." (1986:357). Appadurai's notion of gatekeeping allows us to recognize that there exist other questions, practices, and especially other labor relationships which are capable of providing insight into the logic of cultural practice as the dominant gatekeeping concept "jajmãni system." Yet Appadurai's contribution of "gatekeeping" concepts does not address the political reasons for just why and how particular concepts become vogue while others remain unexamined. Why are jajmãni and hierarchy metonyms in South Asian cultural studies while other pervasive concepts, such as ãdhiyå, are not? As detailed research on jajmãni demonstrates, it was never a system, nor has it existed in its current definable form for more than perhaps one hundred and fifty years (Commander 1983; Mayer 1993). Thus, I argue that jajmãni should be analyzed as part of a larger economic system. As one researcher declared in reference to jajmãni, "As the universality of political economy has receded before the myriad instances of particular economic rationalities, it has become increasingly clear that most non-capitalist structures are organized around a multi-centric set of dynamics (emph. added)." (Commander 1983:283). Whether or not we perceive particular productive practices within a greater framework is significant because it changes the boundaries of our definitions and perceptions of labor relations. The difference is one of subjective/relational versus an objective/reified understanding of labor relations. In the case of the misperception of jajmãni as a "system," researchers sought to understand jajmãni through an epistemological framework based on a Western root metaphor of objectification. The jajmãni-like relationships known as bali, khalo, 369 asami, and bista became an object of study, concretized into the label "jajmãni system." Through this false objectification which essentialized labor relations, we missed the entire subjective range and reality of productive social relations in South Asia. The meaning of an artisan - landowner relationship based on khalo, for example, depends upon linkage to other practices, such as credit lending, which can be statistically measured. L. Caplan argued similarly that creditor - debtor relations in Nepal should not be separated from other social obligations: ...I have attempted to demonstrate that to understand the implications of credit dealings in a small - scale peasant community, it is necessary to consider the wider social context and the total pattern of linkages between the persons involved in these transactions. While the credit tie itself can be heuristically isolated as the focus for a discussion of the constraints of convergent or multipurpose relationships, other kinds of linkage can also provide the departure point for a consideration of the problem. (1972:702). A fuller understanding of the logic of exchange and power in Nepali society implies that we acknowledge connections between labor practice and other economic practices such as loans and credit. By looking at lending patterns of employers and workers, for example, one can see a relationship between bank and indigenous credit systems. Capitalist-oriented local elites draw credit from government banks and at the same time lend indigenous credit. Local low castes and workers are statistically more likely to take indigenous loans rather than bank loans. Workers thus bond themselves through lending into paternal relationships with their employers. This interdependence between patron-lender and client-borrower needs to be recognized by development agencies and His Majesty's Government of Nepal (1962). The policies of government lenders would become more enlightened if they took into account their own role in a larger indigenous set of credit relations. By examining indigenous labor management one also can see the relationship between ownership of property and control over indigenous credit. Many Jãjarkoëi women control and 370 own livestock, jewelry, metal kitchenware, and other movable property (chal sampatti). The ownership of these properties has constituted an important source of lending collateral for women since Nepali collateral loans (bandhãki) are based on female owned movable property as well as non-movable properties. In this way, women have used collateral loans to increase the prestige and wealth of themselves and their families. Bhãrat Sunãr, for example, in Chapter Eight bemoans the fact that "Taramara" and her family are getting too "big;" because Taramara channeled government wages into livestock purchases. In other interviews I also found that Taramara and other women with large livestock holdings further their properties by taking and giving loans using livestock as collateral. This loan form is called bandhãki ko riÿ. Today, however, banks seldom extend loans to illiterate women even if they do have collateral. Thus introduced types of credit tend to "erase" women from their established positions in credit systems whereas indigenous loans tend to incorporate female lenders. Indigenous and introduced loans have been important for understanding women’s roles in patronage. One way to perceive connections among labor practices is to view them through a form of production which I call paternalism. Paternalism is marked by a set of labor relations which accommodate social asymmetry in the exchange of resources, labor time, or services. Paternalism is also characterized by 1) an emphasis on unequal exchange; 2) patron-clientism; 3) land ownership as a primary marker of social status; 4) prominent barter and labor exchange; and 5) workers control their own means of production. There is always an interplay, however, between paternalism and other production forms, such as capitalism, as households negotiate among various economic strategies and labor choices. While paternalism is implicit in Brãhmanical and Western elite renderings of South Asian caste based cultures, egalitarianism has often been ignored by researchers (one exception is Mencher 1974). The ethos of egalitarianism, fairness and an equal exchange of resources and labor time, is often expressed by low castes in Jãjarkoë. Seldom have I read of low caste renderings of how Nepali society is constructed. We have been encouraged to see the 371 Brãhmanical ideals of hierarchy rather than the ideals of egalitarianism expressed by disenfranchised workers. Researchers have also focused on concepts of purity and pollution rather than honesty (sojo, imandãr) and cleverness (chalak), and of dhãrma and karma rather than labor exploitation. As researchers we have been imbued with Hindu elite notions of how society should be framed theoretically. Yet other social constructions of Nepali society exist and these have a whole different slant to the meaning of paternalism and egalitarianism. In interviews such as those in Chapter Eight with Gogane Rawot and Bhãrat Sunãr, I came to understand that these men stress fairness, honesty, and good egalitarian relationships with elites. They do not often incorporate or defend notions of hierarchy and purity, nor even of related practices imbued with asymmetry such as arranged marriage. Such notions are not in their best interests economically nor politically. It follows that many of the values, ideologies, and ethics characteristic of Hindu based societies are experienced, incorporated, and manipulated according to social position (Kolenda 1964). Patronage, for example, is experienced differently by low castes than it is by high caste elites. This dissertation attempts to present both paternalism and egalitarianism as social constructs in Jãjarkoëi labor relations. Since the mutuality of labor forms is difficult to envision, below I present a field of labor choices which defines 1) jajmãni; 2) khalo; 3) haliya; 4) adhiyå; 5) baure; 6) parimã; and 7) sahayog and a few of the other less well known management strategies discussed in this dissertation. This figure below is taken from a poster designed for a recent conference. 372 373 Each working strategy is related to several overlapping options from which the farmer may choose. Some of these strategies are exploitative, some are cooperative. They all require that the farmer make decisions and manipulate her resources. And they are all correlated statistically. A person who responded in my surveys that she does labor for others will also tend to respond that someone in her family is a low caste artisan, for example. In Chapters Five and Seven I have explored the space of labor practices from a statistical perspective using a simple correlation among types of practice which particular classes of people tend to use. Landlords are hierarchically related to tenants not only through the use of sharecropping but also through the use of other labor exchange practices, such as parimã. Certain social positions are hierarchical and contain endemic unequal exchange, as in tenant and landlord interactions. Other social positions are symmetrical; exchange occurs through acts of cooperation such as in reciprocal labor and gifts of labor. In the section below, I shall review some of the ways in which the indigenous labor practices discussed above are related to broader theoretical issues. Assumptions and Realities about Non-Western Forms of Production The belief that small scale producers are ignorant about efficient high-yield agricultural production impedes our understanding of the management of agricultural production in Nepal. There has been surprisingly little anthropological research on the management of indigenous labor, given current demands for sustainable agriculture, fair exploitation of labor, and sustainable use of natural resources. In my dissertation I have shown that indigenous labor management of agricultural production is paramount for efficient and timely farming in western Nepal. Indigenous labor management is not dependent on capital intensive farming, but on labor intensive farming. Indigenous knowledge about labor management deeply affects agricultural production. Nepali households select indigenous labor practices depending on labor supply, cropping patterns, income, household size, land holding size, education, outside 374 income, and other factors. Unfortunately, anthropological research in South Asia has generally overlooked the holistic management of agricultural production, and instead has reified jajmãni relationships of patron-clientage. The assumption that jajmãni ties degenerate over time is another misperception which applies in general to all indigenous labor practices. Anthropologists favored a dualist root metaphor of old, traditional, degenerate and prãkriti versus metaphors of new, modern, progressive and sãnskriti (for discussions of this split see J. Gusfield 1967; R. Miller 1966). While the assumption of traditional and modern as split modalities of worldview has recently subsided in research writing, the underlying notion of the superiority of modern over traditional in large part still operates in development literature (Aryal and Regmi 1982; Audyogika Seva Kendra 1979/80; Banskota and Bista 1980). One exception is that of D. B. Bista who views local practices in labor management as having possible benefits over introduced practices (personal communication, 1990). Another related assumption is that "progress," like the concept of modernization, is measured by increasingly capital intensive production. This fallacy prohibits us from appreciating the management of intensive labor in agricultural production. As I have stressed in the review of the literature, the study of local economic behavior and labor relations has been given to eurocentric assumptions of simplicity, "degeneration," and "uneconomic" farming. Writers, such as S. Epstein (1962), assumed that capitalist economic practices would soon fill the gap between the "uneconomical" peasantry in South Asia and (Western) efficient economical practices. Contrary to anthropological theory, patron-clientage between landowners and artisans (or priests) remains strong in rural villages throughout Nepal. In Jãjarkoë, for example, more than 85% of households interviewed continue using khalo and jajmãni to organize production and distribution of artisan products and ritual needs. The assumption is slowly eroding that local exchange shall be replaced inevitably by commodities and wage labor. Some changes have occurred which are noteworthy and which 375 have certainly affected social relations in Jãjarkoë. For example, many householders stopped planting local cotton trees in the 1950's from which they made ëhetuwa cloth. Recently however, some householders have revived the practice of planting and using local cotton. They find that the materials available in the terai are costly, poorly made, and that dyes are poor quality. Further, the demand for local ëhetuwa cloth rises as people begin to use it for nontraditional purposes, such as in tailoring of men's suits. While it is too soon to tell, it appears that a balance between locally grown and imported materials is being established. Both local and introduced cotton traditions may contribute to the regional economy. Part of my theoretical development on multiple production forms in Chapter Three is based on the recognition that various forms of production, such as paternalism and capitalism, contribute to an economic formation. Several economic exchange strategies besides monetary exchange contribute to the overall economic formation in Jãjarkoë. Barter, labor exchange and patronage are three exchange strategies which deserve attention. As noted in Chapter Two, C. Humphery (1985; 1992) stresses that barter is an important exchange strategy in Nepal. Barter is indeed an important economic strategy for Jãjarkoëi traders. One woman, for example, refused to take money for a large handful (mana) of dried sumac. She demanded two mana of grain in exchange for the vitamin packed treat. With little surplus grain and marketable items being produced in Jãjarkoë, and hilly terrain, many people do not travel to the nearest full time market. On a day to day basis, many people use well known traditional formulas for exchanging unlike products. As Humphery and Hugh-Jones' edited volume(1992) shows, barter belongs fully to complex societies such as that in Jãjarkoë. Slowly the assumption is dissolving that barter belongs to "disintegrating" economies. While it is true that capitalist wage labor is more popular in Jãjarkoë than in the early part of the century, it would be false to claim all labor is becoming capitalist and waged. Reciprocal labor is still common; service specialists and priests still maintain traditional ties of 376 patronage. And even waged tasks traditionally performed by unfree laborers, slaves and bonded laborers are still not truly capitalist. Wage workers in Jãjarkoë earn a unit of grain and sometimes a percentage of the harvest rather than earning money. Most importantly, most wage workers in Jãjarkoë still control their own means of production. Tailors own their machines and work sites, plowmen own their bullocks, and daily laborers own their own land and homes, if not enough land to maintain subsistence. With careful historical research, such as that done by Peter Mayer (1993) on changes in jajmãni, we begin to see that indigenous labor practices do indeed change, though not necessarily into capitalist wage labor. Mayer, for example, claims that jajmãni used to be a communal relationship between service specialist and community before the twentieth century. In the last hundred years, however, the relationship has become individualized with individual patrons negotiating with service specialists. This individualization of labor relations represents a major shift in the social relationships of production throughout areas where jajmãni has been employed. One of the most entrenched assumptions about peasant economies is that villages are either functioning with balanced reciprocity, or conversely, with inherent unsolvable exploitative relations between "haves" and "have-nots." These two polarities of either perfect harmony or unscrupulous exploitation are surely far from reality. In my dissertation I have shown that neither a romanticization nor a negative stereotype of interhousehold relations is appropriate. Rather, a close accounting of labor negotiations and mechanisms for unequal exchange due to patronage will better inform our understanding of agrarian social relations. Disguised within labor exchange and exchange of grain for services lies a relationship of asymmetry. Jajmãni relations are often described by apologists as equal, balanced, or even asymmetrical for the benefit of the community (Raheja 1988a and 1988b, for example). According to Jãjarkoëi patrons, jajmãni relations are negotiated but egalitarian and necessary for the ritual auspiciousness of the community. Such hegemonic depictions of social relations cannot do justice to the realities of unequal exchange. Artisans and unskilled agricultural 377 workers, on the other hand, display fear that they will receive less than is appropriate for their work. Given their precarious economic situation and inferior quality of life, their fears are well grounded. Yet patrons continue to use hegemonic ideologies to assert their interests. They claim that artisans are "like children" and need the control of patrons. Or, patrons claim that worker households waste their incomes on alcohol and meat and therefore do not deserve benefits such as neighborhood water taps, electricity, and schooling. Workers recognize this imbalanced relationship and negotiate their services according to the benefits provided by patrons. Artisans assert values of equality with patrons with sayings, such as one noted in Chapter One, "Just as you provide the food, so we shall sew the clothing." Challenging elites during the exchange process is one way of negotiating for equal exchange under asymmetrical conditions. Researchers recognize unequal exchange mechanisms in patronage, bondage, and daily labor, but asymmetry may also covertly exist in egalitarian exchange (parimã, sahayog). In Chapter Six, for example, I have focused on negotiations in simple reciprocity (parimã) and labor gifting (sahayog). I found that householders exchange labor with householders of similar caste and class positions using parimã and sahayog and create social symmetry in the process. When householders of asymmetrical social standing collude on a labor project, their relationship may be termed sahayog or parimã but this is merely an euphemism. In reality, the weaker partner donates labor to the more powerful partner. One of the most insidious assumptions that I have addressed, and one employed by anthropologists, is that women's work can be subsumed under men's work in researching and reporting (P. Caplan 1988; Recchini de Lattes and Wainerman 1986). This practice omits attention to women's particular roles, problems and needs. I have highlighted the fact that nearly all articles about jajmãni, even those written by women (Epstein 1962, 1967, 1971; Gough 1960; Kolenda 1964; 1967; Benson 1976), take for granted that men's work, not women's, should be analyzed. Given this situation, we lack understanding of how female 378 artisans and unskilled agricultural laborers organize their resources, patron contacts, collection ii of wages, and other aspects of their productive relations. For this reason, I have included references, vignettes, and examples from the female labor perspective. The causes of the invisibility of women in research and reporting are many. I initially neglected to conduct socioeconomic surveys with female household heads. I assumed that men were automatically the heads of households in a Hindu society. It turned out that up to thirty percent of households in a given village were actually headed by an elderly female who did wish to be interviewed, or by a younger female who was separated from her spouse due to migration or family disputes. In addition to my own androcentric categories, I used precepts of "representative" labor relations, such as a male landlord and his male sharecropper. It was not until I had actively looked for the role of women in labor relations that I found many women did indeed own land and have sharecroppers. After I realized my mistake I found many female household heads, landowners, landlords, and even creditors. Looking over the dissertation, I now see the labor practices of many women and their roles in managing social relations. For example, Mrs. Karki (Chapter Seven) managed much of their family's rice transplanting day. Her niece, Sita, owned part of their family's land, employed sharecroppers, and contributed to rice transplanting day. Another pair, Mobi and Bishnu, organized labor swaps (parimã) though their actual number of days traded was unequal. In Chapter Seven, women were "roparni," (female field hands) and "gwaali," (goatherders). Their labor relations with other households were evident in their use of all forms of indigenous labor practices. Later in the chapter, Gogane Rawot described how the women in an opposing political faction had bought many buffalo and had become wealthy and influential. Such influence is talked about in late night gossip and signified in household objects. ••• One of my theses in this dissertation has been to show that labor (material realm) and language (symbolic realm) are not mutually exclusive; they actually give meaning to each other 379 dialectically. All too often economic behavior is isolated analytically from its greater social context. Yet, as I have stressed in Chapter Eight, language can determine behavior. R. Saldívar comments, "Read dialectically, narratives indicate that language and discourse do affect human lives in determining ways, ways that are themselves shaped by social history." (1990: 207). In studying labor practices, I was interested in how labor practice comes to be symbolized and accorded social significance. In Jãjarkoë's hierarchical socioeconomic context, labor practices signal significant pieces of information which position actors in hierarchical social space. Using three examples of signifying labor practice and position in a social hierarchy (the legend of Chatur Malla, the conversation with Gogane Rawot, and the late night conversation with Bhãrat Sunãr), I have contextualized labor relations, and especially social hierarchies, within bounded examples. I have concluded that one of the most striking aspects of the language - labor interface is the ability of language, especially persuasive rhetoric, to influence labor relations. Many signifiers of labor are small and potent; there are an infinite number of mere icons which announce an actor's social position. My favorite signifiers of productive social position were the items people sported such as political buttons, particular commodities, articles of clothing, or how the clothing was worn or constructed. For example, upwardly mobile high caste boys and girls will often join the Red Cross Society in Jãjarkoë. They sport a button, simple in its design of white background with red cross signifying their affiliation. To me, this signified their desire to become part of the "givers," the patrons of those "less fortunate." At Red Cross meetings, members would spend hours discussing their budget, how to spend funds, which family in need would get a donation from the Red Cross. To one who has attended several meetings, the Red Cross is a good lesson in becoming part of the local elite. Although this dissertation is not overtly directed toward an applied or practical discussion of labor relations and their use for development projects, the topic of indigenous 380 labor management lends itself to application in development. Perhaps the first step of any coming together of development and indigenous perspectives is the acknowledgment that "ethnomanagement" can be beneficial to sustainable development. We can create more effective development policies with understanding local labor relations in addition to indigenous technical knowledge. We can also create better interface between Western and local assumptions about development goals if we study the semiotics of local and introduced labor relations. Linda Stone pointed out, for example, that Western assumptions about the nature of development are often not shared by local farmers who are the “targets” of development (Stone 1989; see also Bista 1991). Quite often developers are keen to glean information about local pharmacologies, soil classifications, methods of managing water, and other types of indigenous knowledge. Often, however, such developers have little understanding of the social, economic, and political matrix which are part of human use of flora or fauna. In studying the management of labor, I have necessarily learned about methods of agriculture and livestock production. Knowledge about labor management leads to knowledge about objects being managed. During my research I noticed many interesting facets of indigenous knowledge which should be communicated to outsiders and development specialists. The following is a one brief example of local knowledge in agricultural production: Corn growing techniques in Jãjarkoë differ from techniques in capital intensive environs. Local corn stalks grow in unirrigated, dry and hilly soil beds. The practice of dalnu is therefore used. To do dalnu, a farmer bends each corn stalk to the ground, effectively breaking peripheral root stalks, about three weeks before fruition. Although labor intensive, this practice ensures that the deepest roots continue to grow into deeper, moister soils, thus capturing precious water supplies. Bending corn stacks may certainly be a useful technique which development outreach workers could teach in places where soil moisture is low. Yet this technique would be ineffective unless certain labor conditions are present, including a labor intensive farming 381 support structure. In order to get corn roots to grow deeper, people used baure (called) labor for the corn setting process. Baure, a form of non-capitalist, waged, unskilled labor is appropriate when 1) the family can afford to hire workers for several days; 2) when there is a supply of unskilled workers available, usually underemployed low caste men or women; and 3) the employer owns more land than his/her family wishes to farm. In terms of drawbacks to using baure, August is a difficult time of year to pay workers. The employers must maintain a grain surplus in the pre-harvest season in order to pay baure workers. If the family does not have the grain resources to pay the workers, then the family must organize more efficiently and use sahayog, to request gifts of labor, or parimã, and become part of a circle of reciprocal help. Small scale producers in Jãjarkoë about many production techniques in addition to corn setting. Some of the indigenous techniques in Jãjarkoë, in which development officers were often interested, included new cotton propagation, irrigation management, companion planting, alley cropping, live fencing, rotation of communally owned trees, forest management practices, beekeeping techniques, marketing of forest products, livestock rotations on hereditary pastures, medicinals, and collection of forest greens and berries. iii Each of these types of production has a complimentary set of rules for the management of labor similar to the example of setting corn stalks. In some of these practices labor relations are quite collective and in others wage labor can be practiced. In every case however, the interface between indigenous knowledge of material resources and indigenous knowledge of labor resources is very close. In conclusion, I want to point out that this dissertation is about not only farmers in Jãjarkoë, but it applies to the lives of most of the people in Nepal. Most people are farmers, most have relatives who are farmers, and most of these people know all about the working strategies I have discussed. Even though this dissertation is not about urban Nepalese living in Kathmandu, or industrialists and business owners, it still represents the working strategies of the millions of people who support burgeoning capitalist interests in Nepal. This dissertation 382 respresents working strategies which have not been understood by elites in Kathmandu and the outside world. Some of the work strategies have been previously analyzed piecemeal, such as bonded labor and jajmãni. By turning our attention to the complexity of the many ethnomanagement strategies among farmers rather than to the particular practices in themselves, we can get a better overview of work in Nepal. It is an injustice to separate out jajmãni from other working strategies because this exoticizes the practice. If we keep claiming that these exotic (from the outsider’s perspective) strategies are disappearing (in favor of wage labor), we become ignorant of their real functions. In the name of “development” many local work strategies have been usurped, contorted, or just ignored in favor of the elite outsider’s visions of better management strategies. This does not make for better development of human resources. Jãjarkoëi named labor practices, jajmãni, khalo, adhiyå, hali, baure, parimã, and sahayog, create a network of productive social relations. This network might be described as a gestalt of labor relations because the sum arguably equals more than the collection of its parts (Hoffman 1988; Maslow 1952). Remember, too, that most of the strategies I have discussed are not exotic, they actually have universal counterparts. Reciprocal labor exchange still takes place in the United States. And so does bonded labor in a certain twisted fashion. Remember the U.S. car bumper sticker, “I owe, I owe, so off to work I go...” hummed to the tune from a Disney movie about Snow White and the Seven Dwarves? The character of the working strategies I have discussed are universal, but they take a particular constellation of meanings based on Nepalese historical circumstances. But why study working strategies? Personally, I feel that there are a lot of problems with capitalist work relations. There is a lot of exploitation, a lot of dull repetitious activity, and a lot of resentment and unhappiness. For example, in the United States we have inherited the “slacker” generation. Young adults do not buy into the ideals of hard work because they can see that it will bring them no good, no security, no meaningful lifestyle. And in 383 Kathmandu, many young men and women have a similar attitude. They desperately want to work, but there are no wage labor jobs which fit their needs. The capitalist approach to human resources has many problems. In a global post-modern situation, we will need to draw on alternatives to wage labor. We will need to explore the dynamics of reciprocal labor, gifts of labor, and even more exploitative forms such as tenancy in an attempt to shape better working environments. In the future, we may need to draw on our understanding of non-capitalist work strategies in order to create better working environments. Therefore we need more studies of indigenous labor strategies which explain the complexity of indigenous labor relations in other countries around the world. Yet there will be, and have been, mistakes in consciously manipulating our working relationships. The ujimaa program in Tanzania in the past decades was a nasty example of this distortion of indigenous work practices for the political agendas of elites. But there have been both successful and distorted applications of indigenous work practices, and there will be more attempts to use local work strategies in the future. Hopefully, with better understanding of the gestalt of ethnomanagement, there will be more successful development of human resources in Nepal. i Notes to Conclusion iThanks for this definition are partly due to the work of Dr. Nina Etkin in the fields of ethnobotony and anthropology ii The divisions of labor in pottery making in India and Sri Lanka has been discussed by Winslow 1994 and Crewe 1988. iii Chris Evans of Nepal Community Support Group (NECOS) provided me with numerous ongoing reports of their use of indigenous knowledge in community development. NECOS may be reached at PO Box 3724, Kathmandu, Nepal for manuscripts of these reports. 1 References Cited Abercrombie, Nicholas and John Urry 1983 Capital, Labour and the Middle Classes. George Allenn & Unwin. Adelman, Irma and George Dalton 1971 “A Factor Analysis Of Modernization In Village India in Economic Anthropology and Development.”. Economic Development and Social Change. G. Dalton, ed. New York: Basic Books. Agh, Attila 1980 “Labyrinth in the Mode of Production Controversy.” Budapest: Institute for World Economy of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences. Allan, Catherine 1988 The Hold Life Has: Coca and Cultural Identity in an Andean Community. Washington, D.C.: Smithsonian Institution Press. Alvarsson, Jan-Åke 1989 “Alternative Development in Latin America - An Introduction.” Alternative Development in Latin America: Indigenous Strategies for Cultural Continuity in Societal Change. Jan-Åke Alvarsson, ed. Uppsala Research Reports in Cultural Anthropology, No. 9. Uppsala University, Sweden: Reprocentralen. Pp. 1-10. Amin, Samir 1974 Modes of Production and Social Formations. Ufahamu (Los Angeles) 4:57-85. 1980a Class and Nation, Historically and in the Current Crisis. New York: Monthly Review Press. 1980b The Class Structure of the Contemporary Imperialist System. Monthly Review 31:9-27. Anderson, Robert T. 1966 “Rotating credit associations in India.” Economic Development and Cultural Change xiv (3): 334-339. Ardener, Shirley 1964 “The comparative study of rotating credit associations.” JRAI 94:20129. Arrighi, Giovanni, T.K. Hopkins, I. Wallerstein 1983 Rethinking the Concepts of Class and Status-Group in a World-System Perspective. Review VI(3):283-304. Athrey, Venkatesh, G. Boklin, B. Djurfeldt, S. Lindberg 2 1987 "Identification of Agrarian Classes: A Methodological Essay with Empirical Material from South India" Journal of Peasant Studies, 14(2):147-190. Aziz, Barbara 1978 Maps and the Mind. Human Org 1(8):50-59. Baboo, Balgovind 1985 "Economic Exchanges in an Oriya Village" Eastern Anthropologist, 38(2):117-150. Bailey, Fredrick G. 1959 Caste and the Economic Frontier: A Village in Highland Orissa. San Diego. Barnett, Steve 1975 "Approaches to Changes in Caste Ideology in South Asia" In Burton Stein, editor. Beidelman, T.O. 1959 A Comparative Analysis of the Jajmani System. New York: J.J. Augustin. Benson, Janet 1976 "A South Indian Jajmani System" Ethnology XV(3): 239-250. Berry, Wendell 1977 The Unsettling of America: Culture and Agriculture. New York: Avon Books.1984 “Whose head is the farmer using? Whose head is using the farmer?” in Wes Jackson et al., eds. Meeting the Expectations of the Land: Essays in Sustainable Agriculture and Stewardship. San Francisco: North Point Press. Beteille, Andre 1965 Caste, Class, and Power. Berkeley: U. of Cal. Press. 1969 The Politics of "Non-Antagonistic" Strata. Contributions to Indian Sociology 3:17-31. 1987 The Idea of Natural Inequality and Other Essays. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Binford, Leigh and Scott Cook 1991 “Petty production in third world production today” in Littlefield and Gates, pp. 65- 90. Bishop, Barry 1978 "The Changing Geoecology of Karnali Zone, Western Nepal Himalaya: A Case of Stress" Arctic and Alpine Research, Vol. 10(2):531-545. 3 1990 Karnali Under Stress: Livelihood Strategies and Seasonal Rhythms in a Changing Nepal Himalaya. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press. Bodley, John H. 1982 Victims of Progress. Second edition. Menlo Park, CA: Benjamin & Cummins. Bohannan, Paul 1955 "Some Principles of Exchange and Investment among the Tiv" American Anthropologist, 57:60-70. Bourdieu, Pierre 1972 An outline of a theory of practice. 1977 "The Economics of Linguistic Exchanges" Social Science Information 16: 645-668. 1984 Distinction: A social critique of the judgement of taste. R. Nice, trans. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univ. Press. [1979 La Distinction: Critique sociale du jugement. Paris: Les Éditions de Minuit.] 1985 "The Social Space and the Genesis of Groups" Theory and Society, 4(6):723-744. 1987 "What Makes a Social Class?" Berkeley Journal of Sociology XXXII:1-18. 1990 The Logic of Practice. Stanford: Stanford Univ. Press. Bourdieu, Pierre and Terry Eagleton 1992 "Doxa and Common Life" New Left Review 191: 111-121. Bowie, Katherine Ann 1988 Peasant Perspectives on the Political Economy of the Northern Thai Kingdom of Chiang Mai in the Nineteenth Century. PhD Dissertation, Chicago: University of Chicago Brass, Tom 1986 Unfree Labour and capitalist restructuring in the agrarian sector: Peru and India. J. of Peasant Studies, 14(1):50-77. Braudel, Ferdinand 1983 Civilization and Capitalism: 15th-18th Cent. Vol III: The Perspective of the World. Trans. Sian Reynolds. New York: Harper and Row. Breman, Jan 1974 Patronage and exploitation: Changing agrarian relations in south Gujarat, India. Berkeley: UCP. Caplan, Patricia 4 1982 1988 "Gender, Culture, and Modes of Production" in J. de Vere Allen and T. H. Wilson, eds. From Zinj to Zanzibar. Paideuma 28. Wiesbaden: Franz Steiner Verlag. "Engendering knowledge: The politics of ethnography" Anthropology Today, 4(5):8-12; 4(6):14-17. Chambers, Robert 1983 Farmer First: Farmer Innovation and Agricultural Research. NY: John Wiley and Sons. Chambers, Robert, Arnold Pacey, and Lori Ann Thrupp (Eds.) 1989 Farmer First: Farmer Innovation and Agricultural Research. NY: The Bootstrap Press. Cohn, Bernard 1955 “The Changing Status of a Depressed Caste” in M. Marriott, ed. Pp.5377. 1964 "The Role of the Gosains in the Economy of the Eighteenth and Nineteenth Century Upper India." Indian Economic and Social History Review 1:175-182. Comaroff, John and Jean Comaroff 1987 "The Madman and the Migrant: Work and Labor in the Historical Consciousness of a South African People" American Ethnologist 14(2):191-209. Connell, R. W. 1984 Class Formation on a World Scale. Review, VII(3):407-440. Cook, Scott 1977 "Beyond the Formen: Towards a Revised Marxist Theory of Precapitalist Formations and the Transition to Capitalism" Journal of Peasant Studies 4(4): 360-389. Cooper, Eugene 1984 "Mode of Production and Anthropology of Work" in Journal of Anthropological Research 40(2):257-270. Cooper, Mathew 1987 "Relations of Modes of Production in Nineteenth Century America: The Shakers and Oneida" Ethnology 26:1-16. Cox, O.C. 1948 Caste, Class, and Race. NY: Doubleday. Crompton, Rosemary and John Gubbay 5 1978 Economy and Class Structure. St. Martin's Press. Dalton, George, [Editor] 1967 "The Development of Subsistence and Peasant Economies in Arica" in Tribal and Peasant Economies: Readings in Economic Anthropology. G. Dalton, ed., New York: Natural History Press pp.155-168. 1971 Economic Development and Social Change. publ? David, K., editor 1977 The New Wind: Changing Identities in South Asia. The Hague: Mouton. Davidson, Andrew 1989 "Mode of Production: Impasse or Passé?" Journal of Contemporary Asia 19(3): 243-278. Davis, Shelton H. 1977 Victims of the Miracle: Development and the Indians of Brazil. London: Cambridge University Press. Dobbs, Maurice 1947 Studies in the Development of Capitalism. London: Routledge. Dumont, Louis 1980 [1966] Homo Hierarchicus. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Dupre, George and PP Rey 1978 "Lineage Modes of Production" in d. Seddon, ed., Marxist Approaches to Economic Anthropology. pp 171-208. Durkeim, Emile 1933 The Division of Labor in Society. G. Simpson, trans. Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press. Eagleton, Terry 19 ? "Base and Superstructure in Raymond Williams" in Raymond Williams: Critical Perspectives. Terry Eagleton, editor, Boston: Northeastern University Press, 1990 The Ideology of the Aesthetic. Cambridge, Mass.: Basil Blackwell. Elder, Joseph 1970 "Rajpur: Change in the Jajmani System of an Uttar Pradesh Village" in K. Ishwaran, ed. Change and Continuity in India's Villages, pp.105127. New York: Columbia University Press. 1976 Planned Resettlement in Nepal's Terai: A Social Analysis of the Khajura/Bardia Punarvas Projects. Kathmandu: INAS, Tribhuvan 6 University; Madison: Department of Sociology, University of Wisconsin. 307pp. Enlow, Cynthia 1989 Bananas, Beaches, and Bases: The Role of Women in International Politics. NY: Pandora. Epstein, Scarlett 1962 "Economic Development and Social Change in South India" in G. Dalton, ed., Economic Development and Social Change. pp. 460-481. 1967 Productive Efficiency and Customary Systems of Rewards in Rural South India. in R. Firth, ed. Themes in Economic Anthropology, pp.229-252. London: Tavistock Publications. 1971 Customary Systems of Rewards in Rural South India. in G. Dalton, ed., Economic Development and Social Change, pp.99-120. Garden City: Natural History Press. Erasmus, Charles 1956 "Culture Structure and Process: The Occurrence and Disappearance of Reciprocal Farm Labor." Southwestern Journal of Anthropology 12:444-469. Ferro-Luzzi, Gabriella Eichinger 1986 "The Polythetic-Prototype Concept of Caste" Anthropos 81:637-642. Foster-Carter, Aiden 1978 "The Modes of Production Controversy" New Left Review 107:47-78. 1978 "Can We Articulate 'Articulation'" in The New Economic Anthropology, ed. Clammer, John. pp 210-249. Foucault, Michel 1977 The Archaeology of Knowledge. London: Tavistock. Franke, Richard and Barbara Chasin 1979 “Peanuts, Peasants, Profits, and Pastoralists: the Social and economic background to ecological deterioration in Niger” Journal of Peasant Studies 8(3):1-30. Frykenberg, Robert E. 1977 "Introduction" in Land Tenure and Peasant in South Asia. Robert Frykenberg, ed. Orient Longman. pp. 1-18. Fuller, Chris J. 1989 “Misconceiving the grain heap: a critique of the concept of the Indian Jajmani system.” in J. Parry and M. Bloch, eds. 7 Geertz, Clifford 1962 “The rotating credit association; a ‘middle rung’ in development.” Economic Development and Cultural Change x:241-63. Giddens, Anthony 1973 The Class Structure of the Advanced Societies. New York: Harper. Girling, John 1987 Capital and Power: The Political Economy and Social Transformation. London: Croom Helm. Godelier, Maurice 1977 Perspectives in Marxist Anthropology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1978 “The concept of the ‘Asiatic mode of production’ and Marxist Models of Social Evolution” in D. Seddon, ed. 1979 "Epistemological Comments on the Problems of Comparing Modes of Production" in Toward a Marxist Anthropology, S. Diamond, ed., The Hague: Mouton. pp 71-92. Goldthorpe, John 1980 "On the Service Class, its Formation and Future", in Anthony Giddens and Gavin McKenzie, eds. Social Class and the Division of Labour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Good, A. 1982 The Actor and the Act: Caategories of Prestation in South India. Man 17:224-41. Goshal, Kumar 1944 The People of India. NY: Sheridan House. Gough, Kathleen 1960 The Hindu Jajmani System. Economic Development and Cultural Change 9:83-91. 1980 Social Relations in Rural South India. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Gould, Harold 1958 "The Hindu Jajmani System: a case of economic particularism" Southwestern Journal of Anthro 14:428-437. 1964 A Jajmani System of North India: Its Structure, Magnitude, and Meaning. Ethnology 3:12-41. 1967 Priest and Contrapriest: A Structural Analysis of Jajmani Relationships in the Hindu Plains and the Nilgiri Hills. Contributions to Indian Sociology 1:26-55. 8 Gouldner, Alvin 1979 The Future of Intellectuals and the Rise of the New Class. Seabury Publ. Gorin, Zeev 1985 Socialist Societies and World System Theory: a Critical Survey. Science & Society XLIX(3):332-366. Gregory, James 1984 "The Myth of the male ethnographer and the woman's world" Am. Anth. 86. Guillet, David 1980 "Reciprocal Labor and Peripheral Capitalism in the Central Andes" Ethnology 19(2):151-168. Gulalp, Haldun 1987 Capital Accumulation, Classes and the Relative Autonomy of the State. Science and Society 51(3):287-313. Hanley, Mary Lynn 1989 “Living the trickle up dream: a novel grant programme for the small entrepreneur.” World Development 2(4): 15-18. Harper, Edward B. 1959 "Two Systems of Economic Exchange in Village India" American Anthropologist 61:760-778. Harrison, Mark 1977 "The Peasant Mode of Production in the Work of A. V. Chayanov" Journal of Peasant Studies 4(4): 323-336. Hendrix, Lewellyn and Zakir Hossain 1988 "Women's Status and Mode of Production: A Cross-Cultural Test" Signs: A Journal of Women in culture and Society 13(3): 437-453. Hewitt de Alcantra, Cynthia 1976 Modernizing Mexican Agriculture. NY: United Nations. Higgott, Richard 1981 "Beyond the Sociology of Underdevelopment: An Historiographical Analysis of Dependencia and Marxist Theories of Underdevelopment" Social Analysis 7: 72-98. Hindess, Paul and B. Hirst 1975 Pre-Captialist Modes of Production London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. 9 1977 Modes of Production and Social Formations: An Autocritique. London: Macmillan. Hopkins, Terence K. 1977 Notes on Class Analysis and the World-System. Review,I(1):67-72. Hopkins, Terence K. and I. Wallerstein 1987 Capitalism and the Incorporation of New Zones into the WorldEconomy. Review, X(5/6):763-781. Humphrey, Caroline 1985 “Barter and economic disintegration” Man(NS), 20:48-72. Humphrey, Caroline and Stephen Hugh Jones (editors) 1992 Barter, Exchange and Value: An anthropological approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hunter, Herbert M., M. Sammeer, and Y. Abrahm, eds.. 1987 Race, Class, and the World System: The Sociology of Oliver C. Cox. New York: Monthly Review Press. Howes, Michael 1980 "The uses of Indigenous Technical Knowledge in Development" in D. Brodensha, et al., ed., Indigenous Knowledge Systems and Development. Landham Maryland: Univ. Press of America. Hymes, Dell 1973 "Speech and Language: On the Origins and Foundations of Inequality Among Speakers" Daedalus 102(3): 59-86. Integrated Development Systems (IDS) 1985 Rural Landlessness in Nepal. Kathmandu: Nepal Jaksiç, Miomir 1985 "The Theory of Modes of Production and changes in International Economic Relations" Journal of Contemporary Asia 15(3): 361-374. 1990 "Exploitation in the Model of Capitalism and in the Asiatic Mode of Production" Journal of Contemporary Asia 20(2): 224-238. Kapferer, Bruce, editor 1976 Transactions and Meaning: Directions in the Anthropology of Exchange and Symbolic Behaviour. ASA Essays in Social Anthropology 1. Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues. Kaul, Minoti Charavarty 10 1991 "The Institution of Property Rights in the Punjab: 1849-1912" Paper presented at Annual South Asian Conference, Madison, WI. Kirkland, J. Russel 1982 "The Spirit of the Mountain: Myth and State in Pre-Buddhist Tibet" History of Religions 20(3):257-71. Klass, Morton 1991 "The South Asian Mode of Production" Man in India 71(1): 67-88. Kloppenburg, Jack 1991 “Social Theory and the De/Reconstruction of Agricultural Science: Local Knowledge for an Alternative Agriculture” Rural Sociology 56(4): 519-548. Kolenda, Pauline 1967 "Toward a model of the Hindu Jajmani system" in G. Dalton, ed., Tribal and Peasant Economies. NY: Natural History Press. pp. 285-332. Kurtz, Donald V. 1973 “The Rotating Credit association: an adaptation to poverty.” Human Organization 32(1): 49-58. Laclau, Ernesto 1971 "Feudalism and Capitalism in latin America" NLR 67: Law of Manu [A.Unk.] (I used the ref. found in Wiser 1936) Leach, Edmund R. (ed.) 1960 Introduction: What Should We Mean by Caste? in Aspects of Caste in South India, Ceylon, and North-West Pakistan. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ Press. pp. 1-10. Lenin, V.I. 1977 [1899] The Development of Capitalism in Russia Moscow: Progress Publ. Lewis, Oscar and Victor Barnouw 1967 "Caste and the Jajmani System in a North Indian Village" in J.M. Potter et al., eds. Peasant Society: A Reader. Boston: Little, Brown and Company. pp. 11--54. Lipuma, Edward and Sarah Keene Meltzoff 1989 "Toward a Theory of Culture and Class: an Iberian example" American Ethnologist 16(2):313-334. 11 Littlefield, Alice and Hill Gates (eds) 1991 Marxist Approaches in Economic Anthropology Lanham: University Press of America. Malinowski, Bronislaw 1965 Coral Gardens and Their Magic, Vol I: Soil Tilling and Agricultural Rites in the Trobriand Islands. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. Marriot, McKim 1955 editor. Village India. Chicago: UCP. 1968 "Caste Ranking and Food Transactions: a Matrix Analysis" in M. Singer and B. Cohn, eds. 1976a "Hindu Transactions: Diversity without Dualism" in Bruce Kapferer, ed. 1976b "Interpreting Indian Society: A Monistic Alternative to Dumont's Dualism" Journal of Asian Studies 36: 189-95. Marriot, McKim and Ralph Inden 1977 Towards an Ethnosociology of South Asian Caste Systems. In K. David, ed. Marx, Karl 1967 [1867] Capital: ACritique of Political Economy. Vol 1. New York: International Publishers. 1982 [1965] Selected Works. Moscow: Progress Publishers. 1976 (1964) [orig. 1846] The German Ideology. Moscow: Progress Publishers. Mayer, P.B. 1982 "The Penetration of Capitalism in a South Indian District: The First 60 Years of Colonial Rule in Tiruchirapalli" South Asia III(3):1-24. McMichael, Philip 1985 "Class Formation in a World-Historical Perspective: Lessons from Australian History" Review, IX( 2):275-303. Meeker, Michael E., kathleen Barlow, and David M. Lipset 1986 "Culture, Exchange, and Gender: Lessons from the Murik" Cultural Anthropology, 1(1):6-73. Mehdi, Mahboob 1988 "A Review of the Controversy Around the Asiatic Mode of Production" Journal of Contemporary Asia 18(2): 207-219. Meillassoux, Claude 12 1972 "From Reproduction to Production: A Marxist Approach to Economic Anthropology" Economy and Society 1(1):93-105. 1973a "The Social Organization of the Peasantry: The Economic Basis of Kinship" Journal of Peasant Studies 1(1):81-90. 1973b "Are there Castes in India?" Economy and Society 2:89-111. 1978 "The Economy in Agricultural Self Sustaining Societies: A Preliminary Analysis" in D. Seddon, ed., Relations of Production. Frank Cass & Co. LTD, pp. 127-158. Mencher, Joan 1974 "The Caste System Upside Down" Current Anthropology 15(4): 469492. 1983 "Agricultural Labourers in Peasant Societies: The Case of South Asia" in Social Anthropology of Peasantry, J. Mencher, ed., Bombay: Somaiya Publications. pp. 291-312. Metcalf, Thomas R. 1979a "From Raja to Landlord: The Oudh Talukdars, 1850-1870" in Land Control and Social Structure in Indian History. Robert E. Frykenberg, ed. Manohar. pp. 123-141. 1979b "Social Effects of British Land Policy in Oudh" in Land Control and Social Structure in Indian History. Robert E. Frykenberg, ed. Manohar. pp. 123-141. Check page # Miller, Barbara 1982 "Female labour participation and female seclusion in rural India: A regional view" Economic Development and Cultural Change, Miller, Dan 1986 "Exchange and Alienation in the Jajmani System" Journal of Anthropological Research 42(4):535-556. Miller, Robert 19? "Big Tradition, Little Tradition, Whose Got the Tradition?" Mintz, Sydney 1959 "Internal Market Systems as Mechanisms of Social Articulation" in Intermediate Societies, Social Mobility, and Communication. V.F. Ray, ed., Seattle: University of Washington Press. Mitchie, Barry H. 1981 "The Transformation of Agrarian Patron-Client Relations: Illustrations from India" American Ethnologist 8:21-40. Mittre, Vishnu 13 1977 "Changing Economy in Ancient India" in Origins of Agriculture. Charles Reed, ed. The Hague: Mouton. Mukhia, Harbans 1981 "Was There Feudalism in Indian History?" Journal of Peasant Studies 8(3): 273-310. Mukhopadhyay, Rajatsubhra 1982 "Resource Distribution and Power Structure: A Case Study of a West Bengal Village" Eastern Anthropologist, 35(1):63-72. Murra, John Nair, Kusum 1962 Blossoms in the Dust: The Human Factor in Indian Development. New York: Frederick A. Praeger. Narayan, Kirin 1989 Storytellers, Saints, and Scoundrels: Folk Narrative in Hindu Religious Teaching. Philidelphia: U. of Pennsylvania Press. Neal, W. C. 1957 "Reciprocity and Redistribution in the Indian Village; Sequel to some notable discussions" in K. Polany et al., eds., Trade and Market in the Early Empires. Glencoe: Free Press. pp. 218-36. 1962 Economic Change in Rural India: Land Change and Reform in Uttar Pradesh 1800-1955. New Haven: Yale University Press. Nehru, S.S. 1932 Caste and Credit in the Rural Area . Calcutta: Longmans Green. Opler, Morris and Rudra Datt Singh 1948 "The division of labor in an Indian village" in Carelton S. Coon, ed. A Reader in General Anthropology. NY: Henry Holt. pp.464-496. Orans, Martin 1968 "Maximizing in Jajmaniland: A model of caste relations" American Anthropologist 70:875-97. Orenstein, H. 1962 Exploitation or Function in the Interpretation of Jajmani. SW Journal of Anthropology 18:302. Orlove, Benjamin 1986 “Barter and Cash Sale on Lake Titicaca: A test of competing approaches.” Current anthropology 27(2): 85-106. 14 Painter, Thomas 1986 "In Search of the Peasant Connection" in Anthropology and Rural Development in West Africa. M. Horowitz, et al., ed. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. pp. 195-219. Parkin, Frank 1979 Marxism and Class Theory: A Bourgeois Critique. New York: Columbia U. Press. Parry, Jonathan 1979 Caste and Kinship in Kangra. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. 1989 (editor with M. Bloch) Money and the morality of exchange. Cambridge: CUP. Penelope, Julia 1990 Speaking Freely: Unlearning the Lies of the Fathers' Tongues. NY: Pergamon. Pocock, David F. 1962 "Notes on Jajmani Relationships" Contribution to Indian Sociology 6:78-95. Polanyi, Karl, Arsenberg and Pearson, Eds. 1968 Trade and Market in the Early Empires. Glencoe, Ill: University ofIllinois Press. Pollet, Eric and Grace Winter 1978 “The Social Organisation of Agricultural Laboour among the Soninke (Dyahunu, Mali)” in D. Seddon, ed. Pool, Gail 1981 "Migration and Modes of Production: A Comparison of Jamaica and Trinidad" Labour, Capital and Society 14(1): 54-73. Poulantzas, Nicos 1974 Classes in Contemporary Capitalism. London: Verso. Ram, Hari (Entry) 1915 In, Records of the Survey of India. Part I, Vol 8: A.D. 1871-72; Part II: A.D. 1885-86. Recchini de Lattes, Zulma and Catalina Wainerman 1986 "Unreliable Account of Women's Work: Evidence from Latin American Census Statistics" Signs 11(4). 15 Ritzer, George and J. Daniel Schubert 1991 "The Changing Nature of Neo-Marxist Theory: A Metatheoretical Analysis" Sociological Perspectives, 34(3):359-375. Rouse, Shahnaz 1983 "Accelerated Capital Penetration into Agriculture and Changing Class Formation: A Case Study from a Large Landlord-Dominated Village in Pakistan's Punjab" South Asia Bulletin III(1):1-15. Rowe, William 1963 "Changing Rural Class Structure and the Jajmani System" Human Organization 22:41-44. Ruccio, David and L. Simon 1986 "Methodological Aspects of a Marxian Approach to Development: An Analysis of the Modes of Production School" World Development 14(2): 211-222. Rudra, Ashok 1988 "Pre-Capitalist Modes of Production in Non-European Societies" Journal of Peasant Studies 15(3): 373-394. Sahlins, Marshall 1972 Stone Age Economics. Chicago: Aldine Atherton. Scott, C.D. 1976 "Peasants, Proletarianization and the Articulation of Modes of Production: The Case of Sugar Cane Cutters in Northern Peru, 194069" Journal of Peasant Studies 3(3): 321-342. Seddon, David, Ed. 1978 Relations of Production. NY: Frank Cass and Co. Seddon, David, P. Blaikie and D. Cameron 1979 Peasants and Workers in Nepal. Atlantic Highlands, N.J.: Humanities Press. Seeland, Klause (ed.) 1986 Recent Research on Nepal. Publisher? Shaha, Govinda Bikram 1983-84 (2040-41Bikram Shah) (no title) Village Profile Study of Jajarkot District. Kathmandu: National Development Services Sharma, Satya P. 16 1983 "A Materialist Thesis on the Origin and Continuity of the Caste System in South Asia" Eastern Anthropologist 36(1):55-78. Sharma, Ursula 1980 Women, Work, and Property in North-West India . London: Tavistock. Shapiro, Judith 1982 "Women's studies: a note on the perils of markedness" Signs 7(3). Shenton, Bob and Mike Watts 1979 “Capitalism and Hunger in Northern Nigeria” Review of African Political Economy 55:53-74. Simmel, G. 1978 The Philosophy of Money. London: Routledge. Singer, M. and B. Cohn, editors. 1968 Structure and Change in Indian Society. Chicago: Aldine. Siskind, Janet 1978 "Kinship and Mode of Production" American Anthropologist 50:860872. Srinivas, M. N. 1955 “The Social System of a Mysore Village” in McKim Marriott, ed. Village India. Chicago: UCP. Pp. 1-35. 1965 Religion and Society among the Coorgs of South India. London. Southall, Aiden 1956 Alur Society. Cambridge: W. Heffer. 1988 State Formation in Africa and Asia. Comparative Studies in Society and History [vol. no. ?] n.d. "Mode of Production Theory: The Foraging Mode of Production and the Kinship Mode of Production" n.d. copy Steen, Ann-Belinda 1986 "The Hindu Jajmani System - Economy or Religion? An outline of Different Theories and Models" in Asko Parpola and B.S. Hansen, eds., South Asian Religion and Society. Studies on Asian Topics No. 11, Scandinavian Institute of Asian Studies. London: Curzon Press. Stein, Burton 1975 as editor: Essays on South India Honolulu: Univ. Press of Hawaii. 1980 Peasant State and Society in Medieval South India. Delhi: Oxford University Press. 17 1985 "Politics, Peasants and the Deconstruction of Feudalism in Medieval India" Journal of Peasant Studies 12(2 & 3):54-86. Strathern, Marilyn 1972 Women in Between. Seminar studies, Academic Press. 1985 “Dislodging a world view: challange and counter challange in the relationship between feminism and anthropology" AFS 1, Summer. 1987a "Out of context - the persuasive fictions of anthropology" CA 28. 1987b "An Awkward Relationship: The case of feminism and anthropology" Signs 12(2). 1988 The Gender of the Gift . Berkeley: U. of Cal. Press. 1990 "Or Rather, On Not Collecting Clifford" Social Analysis 29: 88-95. Taussig, Michael 1980 The Devil and Commodity Fetishism In South America. Chapel Hill: Univ. of North Carolina Press. Terray, Emmanual 1972 Marxism and Primitive Society. New York : Monthly Review Press. Theisenhusen, William C. 1989 Searching for Agrarian Reform in Latin America. Boston: Unwin Hyman. Tolstoy 1978 [1878] Anna Karenina. Moscow: Progress Publ. Tsarong, Paljor 1987 Economy and Ideology on a Tibetan Monastic Estate in Ladakh: Processes of Production, Reproduction and Transformation. Ph.D. Dissertation, Univ. of Wisconsin-Madison. Turner, Terence 1986 "Production, Exploitation and Social consciousness in the 'Peripheral Situation' " Social Analysis 19:91-119. Vansina, Jan 1985 Oral Tradition as History. Madison: U. of Wisconsin Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel 1974a, 1978 The Modern World-System, I, II. New York:Academic Press. 1974b The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System. Comparative Studies in Society and History XVI(4):387-415. Watson-Franke, Maria-Barbara 1985 "Production and the Status of Women: An Anthropological Interpretation of Historical Materialism." Anthropos 80:1-14. 18 Weber, Max 19 Economy and Society. Esp. Ch's II, IV & IX. Weiner, Annette 1976 Women of Value, Men of Renown. Austin: U. of Texas Press. Williams, Raymond . 1961 The Long Revolution. London: Chatto and Windus, . 1977 Marxism and Literature Oxford : Oxford University Press. 1973 "Base and Superstructure in Marxist Cultural Theory," New Left Review (82): 3-16. Wisner, Ben 1976 “Man-Made famine in Eastern Kenya: the interrelationship of environment and development.” in? Pp.1-31. Wiser, Charlotte 1963 (1930) Behind Mud Walls. (1st ed. publ. by Richard R. Smith). 1963 edition: Berkeley: UCP. Wiser, William Henricks 1936 The Hindu Jajmani System: A socio-economic system interrelating members of a Hindu village community in services. Lucknow: Lucknow Publishing House. Worsley, Peter 1971 Two Blades of Grass: Rural Cooperatives in Agricultural Modernization. Manchester: Manchester University Press. Wright, Erik Olin 1985 Classes. Verso Publ. Zaman, M.Q. 1982 "Change and Continuity in the Patron-Client Relations among Peasants of Bangladesh" Eastern Anthropologist, 35(4):271-284.